Executive summary

After falling during the financial crisis, the effective tax rate on the labour costs of the average worker increased by 1 percentage point between 2009 and 2013 before decreasing slightly over the last few years and reaching 36.0% on average in OECD countries in 2016. The effective tax rate, or tax wedge, as a percentage of labour costs, is measured by taking the total taxes and social security contributions (SSCs) paid by employees and employers, minus family benefits received as a proportion of the total labour costs for employers.

Although the OECD average decreased slightly in 2016, 20 OECD countries experienced a higher tax wedge on the average worker compared with 2015, while 14 countries experienced reductions. For 18 of the countries with an increasing tax wedge, the changes were less than 0.50 percentage points.

In most of the countries where the tax wedge on the average worker increased, the main reason for the increase was due to changes to personal income taxes (PIT), even though only two countries increased their statutory rates (Denmark and Greece). Most of the PIT increases were driven by a higher proportion of earnings becoming subject to tax as the value of tax free allowances and tax credits fell relative to earnings. In most countries where there was a fall in the tax wedge, reductions in PIT were the key factor, however, lower SSCs also played a significant role in France, Iceland, Italy and Switzerland.

Since 2009, the year where the OECD average tax wedge was at its lowest level since the Taxing Wages series commenced in 2000, the tax wedge has increased in 20 OECD countries, fallen in 14 others and remained unchanged in one country (Chile). In this time, PIT has risen in 13 of the countries with increasing tax wedges: among those countries three countries had higher statutory PIT rates for workers on average earnings in 2016 than in 2009; six had increased or introduced surtaxes; and two had abolished basic tax credits. This report considers how these changes affect various types of households, including single earners, families with or without children, and single parents. In all OECD countries, the tax wedge for families with children is either lower or, in two cases, the same, as single earners without children.

The report also contains a special feature examining how the labour income tax system can provide incentives or disincentives for workers to invest in human capital and skills. Investment in skills is a key factor in fostering inclusive growth and in raising productivity in OECD economies. The special feature presents effective tax rates on skills investments, incorporating PIT and employees’ SSCs for the sample case of a 32-year-old single worker undertaking a short course of training. In this case, the average effective tax rate on skills is 24.9%, which represents the amount by which the tax system reduces the net present value of the skills investment made by this individual. Overall, tax levels on skills are progressive; those on higher incomes and those who earn a higher return on skills investments are taxed at higher effective rates. While tax expenditures designed to encourage worker training can reduce the effective tax rate on skills, in many countries this support is provided in the form of tax deductions for training expenses related to a workers’ current job. As a result, the benefits of such support are often limited for those seeking to change careers and those on low incomes.

Key findings

The average tax wedge in the OECD decreased in 2016 relative to 2015

  • Across OECD countries, the average PIT and SSCs on employment incomes was 36.0% in 2016, a decrease of 0.07 percentage points relative to 2015.

  • In 2016, the highest average tax wedges for childless single workers earning the average national wage were in Belgium (54.0%), Germany (49.4%), Hungary (48.2%) and France (48.1%). The lowest were in Chile (7%), New Zealand (17.9%) and Mexico (20.1%).

  • Between 2015 and 2016, the tax wedge increased in 20 of 35 countries, fell in 14 and remained unchanged in Chile. Changes to the PIT were the main contributor to an increasing total tax wedge in 16 of the 20 countries.

  • There was an increase of more than 1 percentage point in the tax wedge in only one country; Greece (1.06 percentage points), which was driven by an increase in both PIT and SSCs.

  • A decline of one percentage point or more was experienced in two countries, which both implemented reforms – Austria (2.47 percentage points) and Belgium (1.32 percentage points). The change in Austria was mainly due to lower PIT, whereas in Belgium it was caused by lower PIT and employer’s SSCs.

  • Changes to PIT were also the primary contributing factor in most countries where the tax wedge fell in 2016. The exceptions were France, Italy, Iceland and Switzerland. Decreasing employer’s SSCs were the main factor in France and Italy.

Tax wedges for families with children

  • In 2016, the highest tax wedge for one-earner families with two children at the average wage was in France (40.0%). Belgium, Finland, Greece, Italy and Sweden had tax wedges of between 38% and 40%. New Zealand had the lowest tax wedge for these families (6.2%), followed by Chile (7%), Ireland (8.3%) and Switzerland (9.1%). The average for OECD countries was 26.6%.

  • Between 2015 and 2016, the largest increase in the tax wedge for one earner families with children was in New Zealand (1.24 percentage points). The largest decreases were in Austria (2.68 percentage points), Portugal (2.50 percentage points), Belgium (1.73 percentage points), Hungary (1.60 percentage points) and Ireland (1.03 percentage points).

  • The tax wedge for families with children is lower than that for single individuals without children in all OECD countries except in Chile and Mexico, where both family types face the same tax levels. No PIT is payable at the average wage level in Chile and no tax provisions for families with children exist in Mexico. The differences are more than 15% of labour costs in Canada, the Czech Republic, Germany, Ireland, Luxembourg and Slovenia.