copy the linklink copied!

Executive summary

copy the linklink copied!

The economy has been hit hard

The coronavirus pandemic hit the economy hard. Containment measures cut many service activities, while manufacturing was hit by failing foreign demand (Figure 1). The moderate rise in unemployment reflects measures to support jobs and incomes. The downturn comes after a long period of high growth that had supported higher living standards, improved labour market inclusiveness, and fostered faster income convergence.

copy the linklink copied!
Figure 1. Output is set to drop sharply
Figure 1. Output is set to drop sharply

Source: OECD Economic Outlook 107 database; and OECD Main Economic Indicators database.

 StatLink https://doi.org/10.1787/888934150177

A fragile pick-up in activity is underway. Output plunged in the first half of 2020, which could happen again if new outbreaks occur (Table 1, Figure 3). Many services are slowly recovering, while sectors sensitive to foreign demand and international supply chains will continue to operate at low capacities. The economy is projected to gradually recover with the lifting of restrictions, releasing pent-up demand of, notably, durable goods and business investments. Following this initial boost to growth, the economy is projected to enter a more stable growth path with unemployment gradually receding towards pre-crisis levels. If an outbreak occurs at end-2020, a second contraction will follow, leading to higher long-term unemployment and more bankruptcies, and resulting in larger shares of underutilised resources. In both cases, the main risks are large increases in the number of bankruptcies and higher-than-expected unemployment, reducing the economy’s ability to bounce back. On the upside, growth would be faster if foreign demand rebounds faster than projected, especially if international supply chains are restored rapidly.

copy the linklink copied!
Table 1. The recovery will be slow

Single-hit scenario

2019

2020

2021

Gross domestic product

2.4

-7.8

4.5

Unemployment rate

4.4

6.4

5.4

Fiscal balance (% of GDP)

0.5

-8.0

-5.7

Public debt (gross, % of GDP)

66.1

78.4

82.9

Double-hit scenario

2019

2020

2021

Gross domestic product

2.4

-9.1

1.5

Unemployment rate

4.4

6.9

8.1

Fiscal balance (% of GDP)

0.5

-8.8

-8.1

Public debt (gross, % of GDP)

66.1

79.7

87.5

Source: OECD Economic Outlook 107 database.

Crisis-related fiscal measures amount to nearly 4½ per cent of GDP, focussing on providing income support for workers, while buttressing businesses. Moreover, banks have to defer liabilities by 12 months for crisis-affected solvent businesses, while the government has issued guarantees of up 4½ per cent of GDP. In addition, the government is implementing stimulus, amounting to one per cent of GDP.

The economy may need continued support. With the fading of the health crisis, containment measures are being phased out and associated fiscal measures set to be terminated. The transition to a strong recovery remains fragile and may necessitate support to avoid scarring of long-term economic growth.

Long-term fiscal sustainability is at risk from ageing-related spending. The old-age dependency ratio nearly doubles to 60% in the coming decades with a smaller and older workforce. If the pandemic comes back in the autumn, the public debt-to-GDP ratio could reach 87½ percent in 2021. At the same time, pension and other ageing-related spending are rising, adding to the challenges of securing fiscal sustainability. By 2055, such spending is projected to increase more than in almost any other European country. If not countered, the public debt-to-GDP ratio will continue to rise.

copy the linklink copied!

The pension system needs to prepare for population ageing

The deficit in the public pension system is projected to triple. With current rules, future pensioners will spend more time in retirement than almost anywhere else. At the same time, the shrinking working age population impacts negatively on revenues. As a consequence, the current large intergenerational transfers would need to increase further to cover the system’s financing gap.

Pension reform has aimed at addressing rising life expectancy. In 2013, a pension reform to prolong working lives introduced a minimum pension age of 60 for workers with a full contribution period of 40 years and a statutory age of 65 for all. Nonetheless, the effective retirement age remains among the lowest in the OECD.

The state pension system is redistributive, reflecting policy measures, such as a minimum pension and an effective limit on pension benefits, and population characteristics, such as differences in life expectancy. This leads to large transfers between contributors within the system, eroding work and savings incentives, and from younger to older generations. Moreover, pension contribution rates are relatively high, while net replacement rates are at par with the OECD average (Figure 2). Recent reform is increasing replacement rates. Many pensioners have short contribution periods and low-income bases, leading to low pension benefit for most and old-age poverty for many.

copy the linklink copied!
Figure 2. The net replacement rate is close to the OECD average
Figure 2. The net replacement rate is close to the OECD average

Source: OECD, Pension at a Glance 2019.

 StatLink https://doi.org/10.1787/888934150196

Later retirement would bolster sustainability. There is low, although increasing, take-up of the bonus/malus system, which has higher rewards for retiring up to three years later than penalties for retiring up to five years earlier. The system is applicable anytime between the minimum and statutory retirement age, reducing actuarial fairness. Special retirement regimes allow early retirement for workers with full work capacity.

The second pillar is underdeveloped. The voluntary second pillar system has many, mostly higher income, contributors. However, contributions are low as generous tax advantages are applied to low levels of contributions. Thus, accumulated funds are very low, rendering the pillar ineffective in providing additional pension income.

copy the linklink copied!

Health services will be subject to ageing-induced changes in demand

The health care system responded fast and effectively to the health crisis. Moreover, its efficiency compares favourably with peers. Nonetheless, structural problems in the sector raise cost, quality and safety concerns. This is a particular concern as ageing leads to different and higher demand for health and long-term care services.

Existing price instruments in the health sector are ineffective in allocating scarce resources. Co-payments play a limited role in directing demand for health services. The effective use of general practitioners is hampered by payment systems that are not cost-reflective, leading to a high number of referrals to specialists and emergency units. In the hospital sector, allocation of resources is hampered by out-of-date reimbursement rates, soft budget constraints, non-transparent remuneration of doctors and a prevalence of small general hospitals. The guidance of patients through the health system is hindered by a lack of information exchange between providers and uniform care pathways.

The underdeveloped long-term care system is poorly prepared for ageing. Low long-term care spending covers 11½ per cent of the older population, well below perceived needs. The supply of long-term care is fragmented, with different legislation and eligibility criteria. Moreover, most is provided by public institutions, reducing supply flexibility.

copy the linklink copied!

Labour market institutions must prepare for a smaller and older work force

To avoid a rise in long-term unemployment as a result of the current crisis, it is important that active labour market policies focus on the hard-to-employ job-seekers by providing adequate job search support and skills upgrading. Such job-seekers are mostly older, low-skilled and long-term unemployed (Figure 3). Moreover, ageing is making labour shortages more permanent, requiring better labour utilisation and allocation to sustain growth. In particular, digital transformation and other new technologies bring new opportunities for individuals and the economy, which can only be realised through continued skills upgrading.

copy the linklink copied!
Figure 3. The employment rate of older workers is low
Employment rate for 55-64 year olds, 2018
Figure 3. The employment rate of older workers is low

Source: OECD Labour Force Survey and Education database.

 StatLink https://doi.org/10.1787/888934150215

Older workers are often leaving the labour market early. The effective retirement age is among the lowest in the OECD. In addition, many older workers use the unemployment, disability and social assistance systems as pathways into early retirement (Figure 4). Another concern is that many older workers lack life-long learning incentives, hampering their ability to adjust to changing work places and new technologies.

Many unemployed workers lack search and work incentives. Many low-skilled workers have few incentives to enter employment or increase work efforts as their associated income gains are eroded by high taxes and benefit withdrawal.

copy the linklink copied!
Figure 4. Older workers retire early
Average effective age of retirement, 2013-2018
Figure 4. Older workers retire early

Source: OECD, Pensions at a Glance 2019.

 StatLink https://doi.org/10.1787/888934150234

Re-skilling and upgrading skills are essential for improving employment prospects. Many of the hard-to-employ job-seekers are not receiving sufficient training to enable them to gain a foothold in the labour market. In addition, there is limited participation in adult education among the low-skilled and low-paid workers, hindering job and occupational mobility.

The wage determination process has led to a compressed wage structure. Future growth will increasingly rely on improving labour allocation to bolster productivity. This requires better incentives for individual workers to improve their productivity or move to higher productivity jobs.

Workers’ geographical mobility is low, hampering labour reallocation. The small private rental segment is based on short-term contracts, rendering it unattractive as a longer-term solution. The rigid housing market has contributed to widespread commuting by car. This, together with widespread use of old heating boilers, contributes to emissions of CO2 and small particles.

copy the linklink copied!

MAIN FINDINGS

KEY RECOMMENDATIONS

Macroeconomic policies to support the recovery

Public debt is rising but remains moderate by international standards. In the long-term, ageing will significantly raise health and pension costs.

Provide additional fiscal support as needed to support the recovery.

Focus on efficient spending and growth-enhancing investment projects.

Competition in product markets is low.

Continue privatisation efforts and further strengthen corporate governance of State-Owned Enterprises.

Preparing for rising number of pensioners

Recent reform of the public pension system has eroded its fiscal sustainability increasing further the need for intergenerational transfers.

Increase the statutory retirement age to 67 for both men and women. Link further increases, if needed, to gains in life expectancy.

Index pension benefits to price developments.

Old-age pension benefits and the effective retirement age are low while work and saving incentives are eroded by a lack of actuarial fairness.

Adjust the parameters of the public pension system to better align contributions and benefits for all contributors.

Make bonuses and maluses symmetric and applicable at a fixed point, such as the statutory retirement age.

Savings in the second pillar is low, particularly for low-income workers.

Make enrolment in the second pillar an opt-out choice.

Increase the ceiling for tax exempt contributions and reduce the associated tax advantages; introduce matching contributions for low-wage workers.

Coping with rising demand for health and long-term care

The gatekeeper role of primary care is hampered by weak information exchange and low GP density.

Make the per-patient payment (capitation) and the fees-for-services cost-reflective.

Use the per-patient payment to attract GPs to underserved areas.

The many small general hospitals lead to inefficiencies in cost, quality and safety.

Establish required minimum interventions for maintaining services, while giving management greater responsibility in service supply decisions.

Create a nation-wide monitoring system of quality, safety and efficiency.

Planning and budgeting are not performance-oriented.

Introduce selective public tenders for health services

Use updated reimbursements for all acute services.

Hospital doctors’ remuneration contains few performance incentives.

Ensure competitive salaries and performance incentives for doctors.

The low LTC spending is focussed on institutional care with many providers and uneven access.

Introduce integrated LTC with common financing mechanisms and eligibility criteria.

Integrate regulation and provision of community nursing and home help

Facilitate entry of private home care providers through quality and output-focussed tenders.

Adjust labour market institutions to an older and smaller workforce

Social benefits are used as pathways to early-retirement.

Reduce favourable treatment of older workers in unemployment benefit, disability and social assistance systems by curtailing age-dependent rules.

Harder-to-place workers receive insufficient support.

Redirect employment and training subsidies to job-seekers with high assistance needs.

Unemployment, inactivity and low-wage traps are high.

Introduce in-work benefits.

Continue to reduce labour tax rates by broadening their bases and bolstering property taxation.

Co-ordinated wage bargaining hampers labour allocation.

Determine more of the framework conditions at the sectoral level, such as seniority bonuses and minimum wage levels. Give social partners greater responsibilities in the wage bargaining process at the firm level.

Labour mobility is low.

Tax owner-occupied housing as other assets to remove investment bias.

Promote the private rental market by introducing regulation that better balance the interest of landlords and tenants.

Tax commuting allowances along with other wage income

Promote green growth

The population is exposed to high particles emissions from road traffic and woodstoves.

Supplement the replacement bonus for old wood and oil boilers with regulatory requirements and financial sanctions.

Align effective tax rates on different forms of energy to reflect their environmental damage.

Disclaimer

This document, as well as any data and map included herein, are without prejudice to the status of or sovereignty over any territory, to the delimitation of international frontiers and boundaries and to the name of any territory, city or area.

The statistical data for Israel are supplied by and under the responsibility of the relevant Israeli authorities. The use of such data by the OECD is without prejudice to the status of the Golan Heights, East Jerusalem and Israeli settlements in the West Bank under the terms of international law.

Photo credits: Cover © Krivec Ales from Pexels.

Corrigenda to publications may be found on line at: www.oecd.org/about/publishing/corrigenda.htm.

© OECD 2020

The use of this work, whether digital or print, is governed by the Terms and Conditions to be found at http://www.oecd.org/termsandconditions.