3. Assessment: stationary sources

This section examines how Andalusian, Spanish and EU-level pricing of emissions from stationary relate to climate change and air pollution. While climate change and air pollution are two separate environmental issues, they partly overlap. Climate change is mostly due to Greenhouse Gas (GHG) emissions and their impact are at the global level. Even if GHGs are emitted in a specific area, their concentration in the atmosphere will contribute to climate change across the globe. Air pollution, on the other hand, is mostly due to other pollutant emissions with generally local impacts.

After a brief exposition of GHGs and air pollutants, this section presents the taxes or similar instruments1 that apply in Andalusia on stationary sources for these two types of emissions. The main part of the stationary sources analysis covers power plants and industry.2 The buildings sector (residential and commercial heating) is also part of the stationary source category, but as it represents a somewhat smaller share of emissions and is not subject to any regional tax in Andalusia, it is not covered in this analysis. Activities in the agricultural sector (to be understood as livestock farming and cultivation) generate emissions that may fall into both categories: stationary and non-stationary sources (non-stationary emissions in that sector arise from the use of agricultural engines such as tractors). For ease of exposition and given that a large share of emissions in that sector are from stationary albeit diffuse sources, agriculture is analysed in this stationary source section. The focus on the agricultural, electricity and industry sectors enables an alignment with the Polluter Pays Principle, as these are the main sectors responsible for stationary source GHG and air pollutant emissions taken together.

There are seven main GHGs: carbon dioxide (CO2), methane (CH4), nitrous oxide (N2O), chlorofluorocarbons (CFCs), hydrofluorocarbons (HFCs), perfluorocarbons (PFCs), sulphur hexafluoride (SF6) and nitrogen trifluoride (NF3). GHG emissions are directly responsible for climate change through global warming: by absorbing long-wave infrared radiation reflected by the earth's surface, they prevent part of the infrared radiation from being reflected back to space. This results in the absorbed energy being converted into heat.

The global warming impact of GHGs is generally independent of where the emissions occur, but it can change over the years. These changes are mainly measured for GHGs relative to one another: when GHG concentrations change, so does the relative energy absorption of one additional tonne of a given GHG. For example, the energy absorption of CH4 and N2O have increased over the years.

Some GHGs have a stronger global warming impact than others. This mainly depends on their radiative forcing and their lifetime.3 The 100-year global warming potential (GWP100) index takes CO2 as the reference and indicates its relative radiative forcing (the amount of warming) over 100 years4 following the release of one unit mass of GHG into the atmosphere. For example, according to the IPCC Fifth Assessment Report (AR5) (IPCC, 2014[1]), 1 tonne of N2O causes 265 times more warming over 100 years than 1 tonne of CO2, so that N2O has a GWP100 of 265. CH4 has a GWP100 of 28. GHG emissions can then be expressed in CO2-equivalent (CO2e), which is obtained by multiplying the unit mass of emissions of a GHG by its GWP100.

In Andalusia, GHG emissions are principally from CO2 and have steadily declined since 2007. Indeed, they have gone from about 75 MtCO2e in 2007 to about 54 MtCO2e in 2019. In 2019, CO2 emissions represented 80% of GHG emissions in Andalusia (see Figure 3.1), close to the national share of 78% (Spanish Ministry for Ecological Transition, 2020[2]). CH4 represent about 10% of emissions in CO2-equivalent, N2O 6% and F-gases, 3%. In total GHG emissions in Andalusia represent about 16% of the national total.

The sources of GHG emissions vary across GHGs. The main sectors responsible for CO2 emissions are the electricity (29%), industry (24%) and road transport (31%) sectors. The main sources of CH4 emissions are the agriculture sector (56%), waste (29%) and biogenic activities (11%). N2O emissions principally come from agriculture (68%) and biogenic activities (15%). F-gas emissions overwhelmingly stem from the industry sector (above 99.9%), and more specifically almost entirely from the use of refrigerants and propellants. This is reflected in the GHG emission breakdown by sector (Figure 3.2).

GHG emissions emanate both from fuel use and from other sources such as industrial process, cattle or waste. A specificity of CO2 is that its emissions from fuel use are directly proportional to the amount of fuel used. Indeed, CO2 emissions are constant per unit of fuel used.5 Exact carbon emissions associated with the combustion of a given fuel may vary with local fuel characteristics but not the end-of pipe technology or combustion process chosen (U.S. EPA Center for Corporate Climate Leadership, 2016[3]). For example, on average the combustion of one litre of diesel generates around 2.76 kilograms of CO2 be it combusted in a vehicle or by stationary machinery. CO2 emissions from fuel use represent about 80% of worldwide CO2 emissions.

The proportionality of CO2 emissions from fuel use to the amount of fuel used makes fuel taxes a good policy instrument to reflect CO2 emissions in consumer prices (and thus mimicking carbon taxes) or to relate tax levels to specific carbon benchmarks. This is reflected in the OECD effective carbon rates indicator (ECRs), which evaluates carbon pricing across countries, i.e. how CO2 emissions from fossil fuel use are priced not only through carbon taxes and permit prices from emissions trading systems, but also through fuel excise taxes. Box 3.1 provides additional detail on these three components as well as on sectors, fuels and years covered by the OECD ECR. The ECR profile for the Andalusia industry and electricity sector is represented and analysed in Section 3.2.2.

The main air pollutants are sulphur oxides (SOx) and nitrogen oxides (NOx) (generally expressed as quantities of SO2 and NO2), carbon monoxide (CO), ammonia (NH3), volatile organic compounds excluding methane (NMVOC), particulate matter6 (PM). These gases and particulate matter are directly responsible for air pollution.

Air pollution has effects on human health and on the environment. The World Health Organisation (WHO), for instance finds that 7 million premature deaths annually are linked to air pollution.7 Even at the European Union (EU27) level, the European Environmental Agency estimates that, in 2019, approximately 307,000 premature deaths were attributable to PM2.5, 40,400 premature deaths to NO2 and 16,800 premature deaths to ground-level ozone. The OECD’s Air pollution effects indicator, uses estimates of the “Value of a Statistical Life” (VSL) and computes the number of premature deaths attributable to ambient particulate matter (OECD, 2022[7]). It finds that in 2019, Exposure to PM2.5 caused a mortality of 190 per 1 000 000 inhabitants in Spain. Additional details on the types of effects air pollutants might have are provided in Box 3.2. .

The direct impact of air pollutants is often local, and their harmfulness generally depends on local conditions, such as population density, and local weather conditions (e.g. rainfall, wind regime or atmospheric stability). Age, standards of living and prevalence of certain pathologies can also impact the health effects on population. The impacts can also depend on pollutant densities in the air and can be more important beyond certain density levels. The United States, for example, have defined an Air Quality Index (AQI),8 which depends on ground-level ozone, PM, CO, SOx and NOx emissions and ranges from “Good” to “Unhealthy” to “Hazardous” (it has a total of six categories). Individual threshold levels are also defined for each of these air pollutants (U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, 2018[16]). Air pollutants might also indirectly impact climate change.

In Andalusia, air pollutant emissions have followed a downward trend since 2003, with reductions of up to 80% for SO2. NH3 emissions went through a significant decrease up until 2011, but have gone up since, resulting in the lowest air pollutant decrease since 2004 of about 6%.

The main sources of air pollutants differ (Andalucia, 2021[17]). The main anthropogenic sources of SO2 in 2019 are the industry sector (about 50%, with 22% from the petrochemicals industry, 11% from the metal industry and 11% from the non-metallic materials industry, 3% from the oil production industry and 2% from the chemical industry), maritime traffic (22%) and electricity production (20%). For NOx, these are road traffic (28%), agriculture (21%), maritime traffic (13%) and electricity production (11%). For CO emissions the main sources are agriculture (34%), domestic activities (23%), forest fires (13%) and road traffic (13%). Those for NH3 are livestock (47%) and the rest of agriculture (46%). Those for NMVOC are the use of solvents. Finally, direct PM2.5 emissions are mostly from domestic activities (38%), agriculture (30%), forest fires (9%) and road traffic (8%).9

Air pollutants, contrary to CO2 are not necessarily proportional to fuel use. Indeed, their emissions intensity also depends on the end-of-pipe technology used and the combustion process (OECD, 2019[5]).

Air pollution and climate change interact and can influence each other.10 For example, an increase in levels of GHGs leads to temperature changes that affect the chemical composition of the atmosphere, and can make air pollution impacts worse. On the contrary, certain air pollutant emissions may actually have negative radiative forcing, i.e., have a cooling effect on the climate – SOx emissions for example form light reflecting particles (Arneth et al., 2009[18]). Moreover, as explained in Box 3.2. , the interaction of air pollutants with other substances in the atmosphere can result in the production of other components, which do have a direct effect on climate change (e.g., black carbon, O3).

In addition, the management of climate change and air pollution have consequences for each other. First, pricing GHG emissions can encourage a reduction in fuel use, which in turn not only reduces GHG emissions but also air pollutant emissions (and vice versa). Co-benefits of climate policy therefore include better health and environmental outcomes. However, this can also create trade-offs, due to the complex interactions between air pollutants and GHGs described above. This is the case, in particular if, at least in the short-term, reducing a pollutant’s emissions leads to additional atmospheric warming rather than cooling. Second, trade-offs can also arise because of the consequences of pricing. This is particularly the case if fuels are replaced by more sustainable fuels such as biofuels and not by non-combustible renewables such as wind and solar. If sustainably sourced, the combustion of biofuels may result in lower GHG emissions over the life cycle because before being burnt, feedstocks have previously absorbed a similar amount of CO2 from the atmosphere. However, it does all the same lead to higher PM in the air. The first issue can be dealt with, for example, by associating bioenergy expansion with effective implementation of post-combustion PM-control measures, such as filters and precipitators (Portugal-Pereira et al., 2018[19]). Similar issues can arise with carbon capture and storage technologies, which may induce larger amounts of primary energy requirements and hence higher air pollution overall.

This subsection deals with carbon and air pollutant taxes on stationary sources in the Andalusian context and focuses on the Andalusian tax on the emission of gases into the atmosphere (IEGA). A description of this tax is followed by its analysis in the more comprehensive context of carbon and air pollution pricing policies. This leads to the identification of how the current tax system compares with a system that covers emissions more comprehensively and more accurately according to sound environmental tax principles, including considerations for potential economic and behavioural impacts. Proposals for strategic reform options in the Andalusia context are made and best practice examples from other countries are presented throughout. First, this subsection provides a description of the Andalusian tax on the emission of gases into the atmosphere. Then, the first part of the analysis deals with GHG emissions, first with a focus on the industry and electricity sectors and CO2 emissions from energy use: the Andalusian tax on the emission of gases into the atmosphere within the context of other national and European-level taxes dealing with carbon emissions. The second part of the analysis deals with air pollutant emissions. Finally, the agriculture sector is discussed, both from a GHG and air pollutant perspective.

CO2 emissions from energy use in Andalusia

In Andalusia, the electricity and industry sectors11 taken together represent more than 80% of stationary sources of CO2 emissions from energy use. The rest of CO2 emissions from energy use from stationary sources is principally from the buildings sector – or in other words residential and commercial heating. Stationary sources are responsible for 64% of overall CO2 emissions from energy use – with the road and off-road transport sectors being responsible for the rest.

In 2003, Andalusia introduced its Tax on the Emission of Gases into the Atmosphere (Impuesto Sobre la Emisión de Gases a la Atmósfera12 or IEGA), which deals both with GHG and air pollutant emissions. It covers direct and indirect13 emissions of CO2 and of two important air pollutants, NOx and SOx. The tax applies to installations in the industry, electricity and agriculture sectors.14 Inclusion thresholds for covered installations exist. They depend on physical characteristics of installations, such as levels of thermal power, impact energy of material used, production capacity, volume, treatment capacity, storage capacity, quantity dealt with or surface. Emissions from landfills and facilities for the intensive rearing of animals as well as those from the combustion of biomass and biofuel are exempt. Since 2005, the exemption has been extended to CO2 emissions beyond free allocation of installations subject to the EU ETS, “except for the excess that entails non-compliance with the obligation to surrender allowances under that legislation”. There are tax deductions for firms investing in emissions reduction, called investment deductions. The formal design of the IEGA is presented in Box 3.3.

The revenue from Andalusian ecological taxes, such as the IEGA is meant to be used to finance the actions of the Administration of the Junta de Andalucía in matters of environmental protection and conservation of natural resources.15 Moreover, 5% of the revenue collected annually is to constitute a reserve fund to attend to emergency situations caused by environmental catastrophes. In 2020, this tax generated about EUR 1.96 million for Andalusia.

In 2019, the tax covered about 70 installations, all in the industry and electricity sectors.16 In total, these represented about three quarters of CO2 emissions in these sectors.17 The firms they belonged to had an average of 543 employees, and average sales of about 559 million euros. About 40% of installations belonged to the electricity sector or to the autoproduction of electricity (subsector of industry) and the other 60% were all in the manufacturing industry.

Installations subject to the IEGA are rather heterogeneous in the emissions they declare. In 2019, they declared CO2 emissions of 179 301 tonnes on average, ranging between 0 and 1.7 million tonnes.18 For NOx, the average was of 399 tonnes, ranging between 0 and 2.3 thousand tonnes. And for SOx, the average was of 234 tonnes, ranging between 0 and 3 thousand tonnes.

Only two installations received investment deductions in 2019. This stands in contrast to the first years of the IEGA where many more installations invested in relevant emission reductions.19

Despite the heterogeneity in declared emissions, in 2019, half of installations (50%) end up falling into the first tax bracket of the tax schedule presented in Table 3.1 (i.e., polluting units lower than 3). 37% fall into the second bracket. This implies that their tax burden is at most EUR 65 000, which represents less than 0.013% of average annual sales. About 9% of installations then fall into the third tax bracket and 4% into the fourth and fifth. Figure 3.4 presents the distribution of installations according to the IEGA tax brackets.

The administrative organisation of the tax reveals good practice in the coverage of installations. Indeed, the inclusion of installations into the base of the tax is based on physical characteristics, which are more straightforward to verify than emissions, for instance. Moreover, the activities covered are very clearly specified, and avoid confusion.

Andalusia plays a pioneering role in setting up a tax tackling air pollution, which is an important issue for environmental and health reasons, as well as economically. Its tax was set up in 2003, following Galicia, which introduced such a tax in 1995. Other Autonomous Communities have since set up similar taxes, including Murcia and Castilla-La-Mancha in 2005, Aragon in 2007, Valencia in 2012 and Catalonia in 2014. The implementation of the tax has helped Andalusia gain the administrative capacity to manage and collect such an environmental tax. This can be important even in the context of a generalisation of such taxes at a national level. Indeed, in 2014, an expert committee (CERSTE-Comisión de Expertos para la Reforma del Sistema Tributario Español)20 had suggested a state-level tax on air pollutant emissions, which could be ceded to the Autonomous Regions for management and collection.

Moving on to points for improving the design of the IEGA, the remarks start with the use of reference values, which don’t appear to be used correctly. The reference values are based on the threshold levels set in the EPER Decision, but it is not clear why such reference numbers should be used to divide the emissions amount to be taxed. Given the way the taxable base is calculated, the division of emissions by these reference values ensures that this tax applies lower rates to the release of one tonne of CO2 into the air than to that of SOx or NOx. However, there does not seem to be any scientific reason to implement such relative rates, given that the reference values are based on numbers that are not related to relative harmfulness of different gases. Moreover, the exemption threshold then ensures that if CO2, NOx and SOx are emitted below these reference values then the installation faces no tax liability. As a reminder, the EPER threshold levels were set for countries to report the majority of their emissions and limit administrative burden. They do not constitute a limit of acceptable amounts of emissions (see Box 3.3. ).

Second, there is no clear rationale in the documentation surrounding the design of the IEGA as to why the calculation of the taxable base bundles all three gases. A potential reason – but not explicitly mentioned – might be to ensure, for example, using the progressive rate structure, that the release of one tonne of SOx is taxed more highly when occurring on top of the threshold of 2 million tonnes of CO2 emissions than on top of no CO2 emissions. Indeed, in the first case the additional tonne would then be taxed at EUR 53.3 and in the second case at EUR 33.3. If this was indeed the explanation, it would be better justified if complemented by scientific evidence. In fact, as highlighted when discussing the interactions between GHG and air pollutant emissions, it does not appear that the negative impact of one of the gases was worse when released in the presence of the other. Moreover, such a tax base provides the possibility for offsetting the tax on the emissions of one gas with the decrease in emissions of another gas. Instead, covering all three gases (with separate taxes or bases) can make sense from an environmental point of view, to avoid effects whereby, in abating one type of emissions, a firm does not pay attention to the potential increases in another type of emissions.

Third, the progressivity of the rates is not grounded in classical environmental economics principles, especially for GHG emissions (i.e. here, CO2). For GHGs, the harmfulness of one extra tonne of emissions does not depend on how many tonnes have been previously emitted. Moreover, the progressivity of rates does not ensure the cost-effectiveness of environmental taxes, which calls for an alignment of tax rates in order to encourage abatement cost minimisation. Unless the progressive structure can be justified on an efficiency21 or equity22 ground, it is not clear that the principle of progressivity should be applied in this context.

Fourth, the whole design of the IEGA is complex and reduces its salience. Recent research shows that complexity in tax systems can make incentives harder to understand and undermine their efficiency (Boccanfuso and Ferey, 2021[23]). Regarding salience, the tax structure does not highlight the rate paid for each tonne of CO2, NOx or SOx released into the air. For example, a firm emitting 10 000 tonnes of CO2, 3 000 tonnes of NOx and 5 000 tonnes of SOx cannot know how much it is paying for each gas separately. The division of the emissions by the reference values and the bundling of the three gases into a same base hence affects the salience of the tax, potentially limiting firms’ responses to it. Indeed, evidence finds that salience is key to ensuring responsiveness to taxes (Chetty, Looney and Kroft, 2009[24]).

Fifth, the reduction of the taxable base is not necessarily grounded in environmental economics or scientific evidence. The reduction is meant to align with the regulatory field of the EU EPER and is calculated based on the three reference values used to compute the polluting units. Indeed, it sets an effective tax-free threshold at 3 polluting units, which stems from a rationale of providing one polluting unit for each gas free of tax. This, however, even if aligned with the EPER threshold levels, is not aligned with their rationale (see Box 3.3. ). They are set to capture the majority of countries’ emissions and ease administrative burden, not to provide an order of magnitude of minimum levels of acceptable emissions. Moreover, the bundling of the three gases into one base results in this reduction calculation having cross-effects on exemptions for different gases. Taking the example of an installation emitting 50 000 tonnes of CO2, 700 tonnes of NOx and 150 of SOx, the way the reduction of the base is calculated along with the bundling of the bases provides additional polluting rights in terms of NOx due to the fact that the CO2 emissions of the installation are much below 200 000 tonnes. Indeed, in this example, the polluting units due to CO2 are 0.25, to NOx, 7 and to SOx, 1. Hence, the reduction of 3 polluting units in the base “cross-subsidises” NOx emissions because of the fact that CO2 emissions are lower than 200 000 tonnes. Because of this, emissions from NOx have a tax-free threshold of 1.75 instead of 1.

The focus of the GHG pricing analysis for stationary sources in Andalusia is on CO2 emissions from energy use. This is for at least two reasons. First, carbon emissions are the main source of GHG emissions in Andalusia. Second, the stationary sources of emissions covered by the Andalusian Tax on the emission of gases into the atmosphere are from the industry and electricity sectors, which are mostly responsible for CO2 emissions (see Figure 3.2), with a majority of those being from energy use. A discussion on ways forward for coverage of CO2 and other GHG emissions from the agriculture sector, which is responsible for the emission of CO2, CH4 and N2O in similar proportions, is present at the end of the subsection on stationary sources.

In Andalusia, four instruments price (directly or indirectly) CO2 emissions from stationary sources in the industry and electricity sectors occurring at three different levels of governance. At the Andalusian level, as just described, the Andalusia Tax on the Emission of Gases into the Atmosphere acts as a carbon tax. At the Spanish level, the Tax on Hydrocarbons and the Special Tax on Coal are both fuel excise taxes. At the European level, the EU ETS applies to certain GHG emissions from the two sectors.

At the Spanish level, fuel use in stationary sources is subject to two fuel excise taxes: a Tax on Hydrocarbons (Impuesto sobre Hidrocarburos) and a Special Tax on Coal (Impuesto Especial sobre el Carbón). The Tax on Hydrocarbons applies to specified uses of liquid and gaseous fuels, including biofuels, coal tar, crude oil, waste oils, coal and coke-related gases. Hydrocarbons are untaxed when used to produce electricity in power plants or to cogenerate electricity and heat in combined power plants. The Special Tax on Coal applies to specified uses of coal and coke products, excluding peat. Together these results in the selected rates presented in Table 3.2, which leaves out exemptions. As in many countries, however, fuels used for electricity generation and some industry sectors are exempted from taxation. Exemptions are covered (but not enumerated) in the subsequent analysis.

At the European Union level, the EU ETS was introduced in 2005 (Section 2.1.1). It covers CO2, N2O, PFCs emissions from the industry and electricity sectors23 in all EU countries as well as Iceland, Liechtenstein and Norway. Inclusion thresholds vary with the type of installation. In 2020, the EU ETS covered 828 stationary installations in Spain and 81 in Andalusia – respectively 831 and 82 in 2019. This represented 81% of emissions from energy use in the Andalusian industry and electricity sectors.

The different carbon-pricing instruments are summarised in the OECD effective carbon rate (ECR) (see Box 3.1 focusing on three components: carbon taxes, fuel excise taxes and permit prices from emissions trading systems. Figure 3.5 presents the price that applies to CO2 emissions from energy use in the industry and electricity sectors in Andalusia.24 The emissions base is divided into the fuel types used in the sectors. The width and height of the different blocks depict coverage and rates, and their colour, the type of instrument used. In blue are fuel excise taxes and in green the EU ETS. Rates of the Andalusian Tax on the emission of gases into the atmosphere are too low to be visible on the figure, but the tax, its rates and overlap with the EU ETS are described and analysed further in the following.

The ECR profile enables to analyse the carbon pricing instruments used, the effective coverage and rates of carbon pricing in Andalusia, and to compare these with benchmark costs (see Box 3.5). After an analysis of federal and EU-level carbon pricing instruments, the analysis turns to the Andalusian tax on the emissions of gases into the atmosphere. It highlights what it adds to the existing national and EU-level carbon pricing instruments and develops recommendations on whether or how to improve this tax – as reforming this tax is in the legal competence of Andalusia.

Industry is the largest emitting sector from stationary sources in Andalusia in terms of CO2 emissions from energy use, representing 29% of CO2 emissions from energy use. Firms in the industry sector mainly face a price signal from the EU ETS, with a permit price of about EUR 53 per tonne of CO2 on average over 2021. The EU ETS cover roughly 60% of emissions in the industry sector (70% when leaving out emissions from biofuel combustion), i.e. 40% (resp. 30%) of emissions are not covered by the EU ETS. However, 97% of EU ETS emission permits were allocated for free in 2021 (light green). In addition, fuel excise taxes apply to very few fuel categories, with several exemptions from the tax, and at comparatively lower levels per tonne of CO2 than permit prices. Emissions from the use of natural gas, which constitutes the main fuel category in this sector (51%), face fuel excise rates of about EUR 11.6 per tonne of CO2, when they are not exempted; more than half of natural gas emissions are exempt. Diesel and LPG used in industry are subject to fuel excise rates of about EUR 19 per tonne of CO2 on average but taken together represent only a minor share of CO2 emissions from energy use in industry (less than 1%). The rest of industrial emissions (28%, mainly fuels belonging to the category “coal and other solid fossil fuels” or “other fossil fuels”) face excise rates lower than EUR 2 per tonne of CO2 (1.41 on 83% of emissions coal and other solid fossil fuels – not visible on Figure 3.5) or are not covered by fuel excise at all. The vast majority of emissions from biofuels (99%) in the industry face no excise tax, while 1% face an excise tax rate of about EUR 12 per tonne of CO2.

The electricity sector (which consists here in plants for which the main activity is to produce electricity25) is responsible for 24% of CO2 emissions from energy use in Andalusia and its emissions from fossil fuels are exclusively covered by the EU ETS. In 2019, free allocation represents about 2% of verified emissions. Emissions from biofuel combustion are not subject to the EU ETS. No fuel excise taxes apply. In Andalusia, CO2 emissions from energy use in electricity plants stem mainly from natural gas use (48%) and then in almost equal shares from coal and biofuel combustion (respectively 28% and 24%). Compared to the industry sector, the EU ETS provides stronger long-term investment incentives in the electricity sector, where only 4% of emission permits were allocated for free in 2021. In addition, a specific electricity tax applies in Spain. Because it does not send a specific carbon pricing signal, it is not discussed here (Box 3.4. ).

The lack of complementary policies to the EU ETS pricing of Spanish (and hence Andalusian) carbon emissions may be an issue given free permit allocation for the industry sector and price volatility. These issues are further developed in the following.

The EU ETS covers a large part of fossil fuels in the industry and electricity sector, but extensive free allocation in the industry sector erodes the average price signal. Effective carbon rates are typically expressed in marginal rates, which means that these are rates faced by fuel users for an extra tonne of CO2 emissions. Marginal rates assign permit prices to the respective emissions base independently on whether allowances are auctioned or freely allocated. As such, the ETS price component (green area in the Figure 3.5) should be understood as the opportunity cost of emitting an extra unit of CO2 for firms (see Box 3.1) which provides an incentive to contain emissions at the margin. Figure 3.5 thus partitions the price signal deriving from the EU ETS (green area) and provides an estimate of how much of the EU ETS emissions are covered by an auctioned (dark green) or freely allocated emissions allowance (light green).

By driving a wedge between the marginal and the average carbon price faced by firms, freely allocated emissions permits can affect long term decision making in imperfectly competitive markets. Indeed, they can affect investment decisions since they can discourage investment of firms in low-carbon technologies (Flues and Van Dender (2017[26])). Other evidence also highlights lower green innovation in firms where a larger share of allocations are distributed for free (Martin, 2013[27]).

Free allocation shares are gradually being decreased in the EU ETS. Free permits do help alleviate carbon leakage and competitiveness concerns of energy-intensive and trade-exposed firms. Under current discussions at the EU level, in particular in the context of a potential carbon border adjustment mechanism (CBAM), there are increasing discussions to phase-out free permits going forward.

Permit prices alone may not provide a stable price signal for investment decisions. Despite the dramatic increase of EU ETS permit prices over 2021 and 2022 (having reached about EUR 78/tCO2 in May 2022 from EUR 34/tCO2 in January 202126) which has strengthened the carbon price signal faced by firms under EU ETS, their volatility might weaken this signal as it results in uncertainty for investors. This uncertainty lowers incentives for firms to invest in low-carbon technology and projects (Flues and van Dender, 2020[28]). The difficulty to predict prices for the following years, in turn, also reduces the possibility for firms to plan, adapt and avoid investing in projects that a few years later may cause them to have stranded assets. Despite the introduction of the EU ETS Market Stability Reserve (MSR), carbon price support mechanisms such as those in the United Kingdom (UK) or the Netherlands (see Box 3.6. ) may be useful to further address permit price volatility.

A strength of emissions trading systems is that they impose a uniform carbon price on emissions from different fuels and sectors. Contrary to existing fuel excise taxes, which are generally fuel-specific and are set per physical unit or per unit of energy and include generous exemptions, emissions trading systems permit prices are expressed per tonne of CO2, so result in all fuels within the covered share of the sector facing the same carbon price. This can help avoid switching to fuels that may be less polluting, but remain carbon-intensive all the same, and increases efficiency, by leaving it up to the polluters themselves to decide on which fuel to cut emissions in the least costly manner. Note however, that this is not to say that fuel excise taxes cannot result in the same rate per tonne of CO2. If first expressed per tonne per CO2 and transformed per litre or GJ for example, this could be the case. However, this is generally not how fuel excise tax rates are set.

It is also worth stressing that the many exemptions from the Spanish fuel excise which are depicted in Figure 3.5 (no blue bar) can lead to inefficiencies and distributional concerns across firms. For example, fuels used for chemical reduction are all exempt from the national fuel excise tax. This results in a lack of incentives for mitigation emissions for that activity even though it might be highly emitting. Often such exemptions are included to address competitiveness concerns that domestic users may face compared with firms in countries where energy taxes are lower. However, the current structure of the fuel excise does not provide relief based on the actual exposure of a sector to international competition. Alternatively, in the EU ETS, measures to address competitiveness concerns relate to the trade-exposure and energy-intensity of production. Additionally, this may generate distributional concerns between firms if firms conducting chemical reduction are larger than others. Moreover, the low rates observed for coal and hence coal emissions are not aligned with the high emission intensity of this fuel. The much lower rates observed for coal (EUR 1.6/tCO2) than for natural gas (EUR 11.6/tCO2) do not incentivise switching to cleaner fuels. Finally, the exemption of most biofuels from fuel excise taxes is generally justified through a life-cycle perspective on biofuels. Indeed, if sustainably sourced, biofuels may be carbon-neutral over the life cycle.27 However, biofuel combustion raises other issues such as air pollution, which are further discussed in section 3.2.3 of the analysis.

ECRs in Andalusia in 2021 deriving from national fuel excise taxes and the EU ETS were already more or less aligned with price levels that are either consistent with attaining 2030 emissions-mitigation goals or that reflect the externalities caused by CO2 emissions. This is even more so with recent EU ETS permit prices going beyond EUR 70/tCO2.28 Such benchmark prices are further discussed in Box 3.5 showing that several studies find that carbon prices of EUR 30/tCO2 in 2021, of at least EUR 60 in 2025 and around EUR 125 in 2030 would be consistent with carbon neutrality goals – under complementary policies and technological development and deployment assumptions. Regarding external cost pricing, a recent study by the European Commission (Mottershead et al., 2021[29]) highlights a central estimate for the social cost of carbon (SSC) of EUR 100/tCO2.

Focusing on the low-end EUR 30/tCO2 benchmark in 2021, the analysis above shows that priced emissions in both sectors of interest go beyond this benchmark, but this stems from the EU ETS. In the industry sector, about 60% of emissions are covered by the EU ETS and 76% in the electricity sector – respectively 70% and 100% when leaving out emissions from biofuel combustion. However, the price signal stems almost exclusively from the EU ETS, raising potential issues discussed above. First this implies that the benchmark is only reached for marginal rates and not average rates that take into account free allocation – especially in the industry sector, where also generous tax exemptions are prevalent. Second, price volatility may result in lower prices – and therefore low incentives for decarbonisation – in the future. This is difficult to control without a carbon price floor. Moreover, even when leaving out emissions from biofuel combustion, 23% of CO2 emissions in the industry sector remain unpriced, and 8% priced at an average rate of about EUR 12/tCO2. Hence, about a quarter of emissions in the industry sector face no price induced signal to mitigate emissions, and the remaining emissions face a price signal that is too low to trigger the required level of emissions mitigation.

In the coming years, the EUR 60 benchmark would be reached on emissions subject to the EU ETS if permit prices stabilise or continue increasing at the same rate – at least for marginal prices. If they increase, they could enable attaining the EUR 100 social cost of carbon estimate. However, fuel excise rates on emissions not covered by the EU ETS remain too low to induce the transformational changes that would need to take place in the industry sector. Moreover, for emissions subject to the EU ETS they provide no underlying price stability or average price signal. While this could be reformed at the national level – and more effectively and efficiently so, Andalusia could use its regional tax to help achieve these goals.

The Andalusian Tax on the Emission of Gases into the Atmosphere hardly adds to EU-wide and national-level price signals both because of its coverage and because of its rate levels. Indeed, its marginal rate can never be higher than EUR 0.07/tCO2.29 In practice, no installation goes beyond the fourth bracket of the effective schedule, implying a maximum marginal rate of EUR 0.06/tCO2. Out of about 90 installations covered by the EU ETS or the IEGA, 59% are covered by both, 13% only by the IEGA and 28% only by the EU ETS. Only one installation covered by the IEGA faces a positive tax liability. The average (weighted by CO2 emissions) marginal rate faced by installations covered by both is EUR 0.036/tCO2. Out of the 13% of installations covered by IEGA and not the EU ETS only one installation faces a positive tax liability (with a marginal rate of EUR 0.025/tCO2) – the others face a null tax.

Many reasons could underlie the introduction of the IEGA: (i) base broadening; (ii) increasing carbon price levels to benchmark costs; (iii) providing a backstop to volatile EU ETS permit prices or (iv) raising revenue. The first three would be aligned with environmental considerations and are discussed below.

Base broadening would increase carbon pricing coverage of emissions to smaller firms or other sectors but given the large overlap between EU ETS covered firms and firms subject to the IEGA, the tax has not achieved such an objective. Moreover, the rates faced by firms covered only by the IEGA are almost all null, and the IEGA thus does not strongly extend carbon-price coverage to emissions in the industry sector that currently do not face a carbon price. As highlighted in the above analysis, in effect, it does not extend coverage to other sectors (e.g., agriculture) either.

Given the very low marginal rates, the IEGA hardly increases carbon price signals either. These rates do not bring marginal price levels close to benchmark costs, nor do they provide enough incentives to decrease emissions by a significant amount. Recent evidence (D’Arcangelo et al., 2022[33]) shows that a EUR 10/tCO2 increase in effective carbon rates would lead to a decrease of about 4% of emissions in the industry and electricity sectors in the long run. As a reminder, the average (weighted by CO2 emissions) marginal IEGA tax rate faced by installations covered by both the IEGA and the EU ETS is of about EUR 0.04/tCO2. However, the responsiveness estimates just mentioned imply that an increase in rates of EUR 0.04/tCO2, imply an decrease in emissions for these installations of 0.016% in the long run – much below the efforts currently required to reach net zero emissions.

At such low rates, the IEGA cannot provide a backstop to volatile permit prices. Indeed, as highlighted above, such rates cannot provide a strong, stable and complementary price signal to the EU ETS. Moreover, its design does not lend itself to such an opportunity. This could occur if it were designed with similar features to the UK carbon price floor or the Dutch carbon levy described in Box 3.6. , with credible price signals, aligned to a certain extent with marginal abatement costs in these sectors. Moreover, the price signal could gradually increase over time to enable firms and investors to adapt and plan.

The opportunities for an Andalusian-level carbon tax of increasing base coverage (to smaller firms for instance), of increasing price levels or of providing a strong, stable and complimentary price signal to the EU ETS could come with political, competitiveness, leakage and administrative costs. The extension to smaller firms could engender high administrative costs if the tax were to be applied downstream, as the emissions measurement costs could be very high, given that their emissions are currently not measured – neither for the EU ETS nor for EPER. Moreover, the difficulty of introducing a significant unilateral carbon tax in smaller jurisdictions must be acknowledged. First, given that climate change is a global issue, the impacts of which are not necessarily felt locally, political support for an increase in rates may be limited. Second, competitiveness concerns for industries that are highly emitting already exist at a national level, and may be exacerbated at a regional level, where firms could relocate easily to neighbouring regions (which would result in carbon leakage). Combining carbon pricing with complementary policy measures can help alleviate competitiveness concerns, while keeping the incentive to mitigate emissions in place, as discussed below. Finally, in terms of effectiveness, climate change and GHG mitigation are best dealt with at a national or even supranational level. Indeed, this enables emissions cuts where they are the cheapest at a much larger scale and can help avoid carbon leakage. Hence, taxing greenhouse gas emissions is not necessarily recommended at a regional level.

The potential administrative issues highlighted above may be tackled through various means. The administrative burden of monitoring, reporting and verifying that would be faced if a downstream tax were to be applied to smaller firms could be tackled through an upstream implementation of the Andalusia tax. This could also be done through the introduction of a carbon tax component on fuel taxes, aligned with their CO2 emissions. However, this may only be possible at a national level.

Potential political, competitiveness and relocation concerns from unilateral carbon pricing were recently tackled by the Netherlands who introduced a gradually increasing carbon price floor in industry, through a careful phase in of base and rates, and the provision of (costly) subsidies. The Netherlands introduced a national carbon levy in 2021 (Box 3.6. ). Political hurdles were addressed by engaging in dialogue with key stakeholders in the industry. Competitiveness issues were addressed by a careful and pre-announced phase-in of base and rates (see Table 3.3). This decreases uncertainty for investors and enables firms to adapt and plan, in order to switch to cleaner modes of production. Going forward, this also avoids the risk of stranded assets, and ensures firms remain competitive in a cleaner production environment. Finally, the careful use of technology subsidies to ease the transition for firms was another way competitiveness concerns were tackled by the Netherlands. Such subsidies can be at the research and development (R&D) or at the adoption and deployment level. These could also help deal with affordability concerns facing firms, especially if the carbon price were increased.

Finally, the tax could cover other GHGs not covered by a national tax, such as methane or nitrous oxide, but the issue of the lack of effectiveness of tackling climate change at a regional level would remain. It may make more sense to try and tackle more local issues, such as air pollution, which is what this Section now turns to. The possible extension of the tax to farming is addressed last.

In Andalusia, the only pricing instrument that applies directly to air pollutant emissions is the IEGA. By pricing GHG emissions, the EU ETS and national fuel excise taxes affect fuel consumption and hence air pollution (OECD, 2019[5]), but the effect is indirect. Hence these latter instruments are not discussed in this section and the focus is on the IEGA.

The calculation of the taxable base implies that marginal rates faced by an additional tonne of NOx (resp. SOx) range between EUR 0 and EUR 140 (resp. EUR 0 and EUR 93.3). Table 3.4 presents these rates according to the bracket which they belong to. The analysis of the 70 installations facing the IEGA in 2019 shows that in practice, 50% of installations face zero marginal rates for their NOx and SOx emissions and that 37% of installations face marginal rates of EUR 50/tNOx of EUR 33.3/tSOx. The maximal marginal rates faced are of EUR 120/tNOx and EUR 80/tSOx. This results in emissions-weighted average marginal rates of about EUR 40/tNOx and EUR 21/tSOx.

Usual estimates of NOx and SOx-associated costs generally show higher costs for NOx than for SOx. However, recent estimates provided by the European Commission (Mottershead et al., 2021[29]), find NOx costs of EUR 6/kg/year on average (i.e. EUR 6 000/t/year) and SOx costs of EUR 7.9/kg/year on average (i.e. EUR 7 900/t/year). However, these costs alone should not impact the level of tax set for these pollutants. The price elasticity of these emissions should also be accounted for.

Few elasticity estimates of air pollutant emissions to taxes exist. Descriptive evidence and models find that such taxes do coincide with decreases in emissions (Juřík and Braathen, 2021[36]; Mardones and Cabello, 2019[37]). Moreover, with increasingly emerging abatement technologies and the decrease in their price, elasticities are bound to increase in the coming years. Decreasing air pollutant emissions from stationary sources can be done through fuel switching, through the adoption of technologies, in particular abatement technologies, through efficient production processes or through decrease in production. The first three options are increasingly within reach for firms and enable them to maintain their output while decreasing local air pollution. Shapiro and Walker (2018[38]) find that the decrease by 60% of manufacturing firms’ air pollution in the United States was accompanied by a substantial increase in manufacturing output. They show that these emissions reductions were primarily driven by changes in emissions intensity.

The Andalusian rates (EUR 63/tNOx and EUR 56/tSOx on average – i.e. weighted by emissions) are in the lower range of air pollution tax rates in other countries but similar to other rates observed in Spain. In Catalonia, they are of EUR 45/tSOx and EUR 75/tNOx and in Aragon they are equal to EUR 50/t for both SOx and NOx. In the Czech Republic, they are of EUR 152/tNOx and EUR 191/tSO2. They are of the same order of magnitude than minimum rates in Chile (see Box 3.7 ). Increasing these rates might be considered an option, but this would also depend on technologies available and their costs.

Air pollution health externalities are local and depend in particular on local population density. Population density is very heterogeneous in Andalusia, mostly concentrating around the largest cities and on the Southern coast (Figure 3.7). Hence, at the same emissions level, the air pollution impact on human health of a firm located in the Northern part of Andalusia should be lower than that of a firm located, for example between Malaga and Marbella.

The differential impacts of air pollution depending on population density are reflected in the Chilean green taxes on PM, SO2 and NOx from stationary sources that were introduced in 2015. Box 3.7 provides additional detail on the design of this tax, and the different local conditions taken into account. Of course, many effects may be accounted for when considering the impacts of air pollution (wind for example), but at the first order, population density matters for health-related issues. The Chilean green taxes also account for levels of pollutant concentration: the higher the initial level of air pollutant concentration, the worse is the impact of the emission of an extra tonne of air pollutant.

Taking into account population density or levels helps to better price external costs associated to local air pollutants and can discourage firms to settle in densely populated areas. Better pricing of environmental externalities implied by air pollution by adapting the tax to local characteristics is important. A price signal aligned with local population levels can help bring pollution to levels in line with how harmful they are. Moreover, this may be more easily sustained politically as well because air pollution impacts are generally very localised and occur on a shorter time horizon than climate change, so are felt more strongly by the population. Another effect can arise, which is to go beyond a reduction in existing firms’ emissions and discourage new firms from settling in populated areas, where their activity would be much more harmful than in low density areas. As can be seen in the comparison presented in Box 3.7 , such a design of air pollutant taxes can make it prohibitively expensive for firms to settle in such areas. Hence such an adjustment to the tax could allow both intensive (reduction of emissions in a location) and extensive margins (less new polluting firms in a location) adjustment to be at play.30 Accounting for pre-existing air pollution density levels (based on indicators such as the US AQI) would also help the design of the tax to better aligned with external costs and have similar effects as those just described.

Regional environmental authorities could provide high-resolution baseline air pollution maps, which would allow these additional factors to be incorporated in the design of air pollutant taxes in Andalusia. Dispersion studies, which would identify the exact areas affected by pollution, could be combined with the sophisticated population georeferencing that is maintained by the Institute of Statistics and Cartography of Andalusia (IECA). In addition to population values, the IECA provides details on other demographic, health, economic and social variables that would enable air pollutant taxes to account for other parameters related to population vulnerability that influence the estimation of the health impact of pollution. However, careful attention should be given to balancing design and administrative complexity with the precise alignment of rates with environmental and health externalities. Indeed, many factors influence the health and environmental impact of air pollution and accounting for all of them would make these taxes unmanageable – so a focus on the main factors is recommended.

Extending the base of the tax to cover PM emissions and emissions from the combustion of biofuels and biomass could be considered as options. Indeed, given the tax already covers NOx and SOx, which are closely linked to PM (see section 3.1.2), the extension to PM would be straightforward to implement. This could have a sizeable impact on one of the most harmful air pollutants on human health. Moreover, while the exemption of biofuel combustion from a tax on CO2 emissions can be justified from a life-cycle perspective (see section 3.2.2), this is not the case concerning air pollutants. Indeed, biomass combustion may worsen local air pollution, especially from particulate matter (PM) and nitrogen oxides (NOx) emissions, which is not compensated for from a life-cycle point of view. The 2021 proposed revision to the EU ETD (European Commission, 2021[41]) goes in this direction, by considering minimum taxation rates for biofuels.

The rates might have been set to ensure progressivity between more or less polluting firms if this is linked to their size, but distributional impacts or equity considerations can, and generally should, be addressed through other policy instruments. Revenue recycling options could be considered, such as support to firms for adoption of abatement technologies. For example, the revenues of the French tax on air pollution were earmarked for abatement subsidies and the financing of air quality surveillance systems (Millock and Nauges, 2003[42]).

Regarding potential competitiveness issues, the Spanish context is such that these might be limited. Indeed, the examples of Aragon and Catalonia show that higher rates can be applied in the long term. Moreover, the higher rates or similar rates observed in other Autonomous Communities also alleviate competitiveness concerns for Andalusia with respect to other Spanish firms. In this respect, the White Book for Tax Reform in Spain recommends maintaining existing regional taxes and introducing a national tax that sets a minimum tax base and tax rates.

Finally, political hurdles might be easier to address in the context of local air pollution, as, contrary to GHG emissions, effects are very local and can be felt in the short term. Moreover, as highlighted in section 3.1.2, reducing air pollution may also be helpful for firms’ economic output.

In Andalusia, the agricultural sector is responsible for a major share of air pollutant emissions, especially for NOx, NH3 and PM emissions, as well as of GHG emissions other than CO2 – it is the main source of N2O and CH4 emissions. Managing emissions from the farming sector hence requires the coverage of different emissions. Pricing these air pollutant emissions as well as N2O and CH4 emissions in this sector would be important to align with the Polluter Pays principle. Moreover, the growth of farming areas and the expansion of urban centres increases the exposure of the Andalusian population to these local air pollutants.

Given the difficulty of measuring emissions in this sector, which are generally diffuse (as opposed to point source), the administrative organisation of managing emissions in agriculture may need to be different from other stationary source sectors.

Given the economic importance of the agricultural sector especially in Andalusia, political hurdles may be important. This stresses the importance of building a strong dialogue and cooperation with this sector. Agriculture holds an important part in the Andalusian economy. It made up 6.7% of Andalusian Gross Value Added (GVA) in 202131 and represented 30.8% of Spanish agricultural GVA (INE, 2023[43]) – and agricultural areas in Andalusia have been increasing in the past years (Junta de Andalucia, 2019[44]). The NOx and direct PM emissions from the agricultural sector in Andalusia mostly stem from fuel combustion. This is best managed by fuel excise duties that reflect the fuels’ environmental damage, as recently put forward by the proposed EU ETD reform. In the face of such high fuel emissions, reduced rates for the agricultural sector should be avoided.

NH3 emissions in Andalusia almost entirely stem from agricultural activities. These include livestock waste and the heavy use of nitrogen fertilisers. For poultry farms, manure is the main NH3 emitter. NH3 then combines with other air pollutants from combustion (NOx and SOx) to create PM2.5 (Bauer, Tsigaridis and Miller, 2016[45]; Lelieveld et al., 2015[46]). Some researchers point to the need of reducing nitrogen fertiliser use, while other researchers argue that the decrease in NOx and SOx emissions would be enough to limit the creation of PM and hence limit health damage of NH3 emissions.32 While in many regions and countries, NOx mostly stems from the road transport, electricity and industry sectors, in Andalusia, this gas is also a result of agricultural activities. Hence, limiting PM emissions in Andalusia could not only rely on other sectors, and the agricultural sector would have to be involved. Moreover, NH3 also impacts soil and water acidification (see Part III, Section 6) and may harm animals themselves, resulting in short and long-term losses for farmers themselves.

NH3 emissions might be better managed through the taxation of intrants and livestock numbers or through regulation and promotion of different agricultural practices. Indeed, NH3 emissions are complex to measure directly (Herrero et al., 2021[47]). Hence, these emissions could for instance, be better managed through taxation of nitrogen fertilisers. A tax on livestock numbers, however, might not give the right incentives to decrease emissions and a tax on nitrogen fertilisers could be avoided by purchasing this intrant outside of regional borders. Regulation, through the promotion of certain agricultural practices could also contribute to decreasing emissions, through for example livestock waste management methods which are less polluting. Moreover, the type of manure management system that is used in livestock and poultry production can also affect emission levels (Dunkley and Dunkley, 2013[48]). Promoting the use of less polluting manure compositions and management can constitute a key element in decreasing NH3 emissions in the sector. Finally, sustainable management practices to enhance nitrogen use efficiency are also key to mitigating NH3 as well as N2O emissions. Pan et al. (2022[49]) propose options.

Regarding other GHG emissions, CH4 mostly stems from livestock, while N2O emissions result from both livestock and soil management. NH3 is also a precursor to N2O.

Current proposals for the taxation of farm-level emissions include considerations on nitrogen fertiliser application as well as livestock rearing. Based on the GHG footprint of mineral fertilisers, Anderson and Bonnis (2021[50]) propose an average rate of EUR 1 to 2 for a tax on the surplus application of nitrogen. New Zealand is, at the time of writing, one of the first countries to consider taxing GHG emissions at a farm level. This is taking place within a long-term process of cooperation and dialogue with farmer associations,33 and in a context where agriculture is responsible for about half of nation-wide emissions. The current consultation document (Ministry for the Environment and Ministry for Primary Industries, 2022[51]) proposes a model which accounts for farm area, stock reconciliation, livestock production data and total synthetic nitrogen fertiliser use. Such an approach could also be interesting for the taxation of NH3 emissions.The risk of relocation to other Autonomous Communities or Portugal is limited. Political hurdles, however, may be important, as can be seen with the protests taking place in New Zealand following the government’s confirmation of plans to price farm-level GHG emissions.34 This is especially so when the sector is an important backbone of the local economy.

This stresses the importance of accompanying farmers through the transition, of enabling them to measure their emissions and to propose viable solutions for them to decrease emissions. A slow phase-in of tax rates can enable farmers to plan and adapt. Programs such as OverseerFM35 can help farmers better manage their intrants and get a better grip of their environmental impacts. The promotion of new technologies and of better farming practices can also provide options for farmers to switch to less emitting practices. The New Zealand proposal also includes payments to farmers using approved mitigation technologies or approved on-farm vegetation. In the long run, it also includes revenue recycling in part to funding for R&D to lower on-farm emissions.36 Improvements would be built into the system, as can already be seen with the consultation process, which leaves many questions open for farmer organisations to get a say (Ministry for the Environment and Ministry for Primary Industries, 2022[51]). Payments to farmers could also be made on the basis of adoption of recommended farming practices and could be based on proceeds of the tax. The recently published White Book for Tax Reform in Spain,37 suggests a gradual introduction of such taxes along with a share of the revenues dedicated to technological improvements in the sector to facilitate their introduction.

Regarding GHG emissions, the recommendation for dealing with such emissions at least at the national level remain, though an engagement with farmers at this stage would be an important step for future pricing or regulation measures to be introduced in this sector. Moreover, given that the Andalusian agricultural sector represents an important share of the Spanish agricultural sector, dealing with GHG in this sector at the regional level could be justified.

The Andalusian tax on the emission of gases into the atmosphere (IEGA) follows good administrative practice in designating covered entities through physical characteristics and plays a pioneering role in air pollutant emissions pricing in Spanish regions. It also presents an interesting feature through its effort to cover CO2 emissions as well as NOx and SOx emissions.

However, the IEGA presents a design that is complex, which might mute its price signal and provide unintended incentives. This is mainly due to the bundling of all three gases into one single base, and through the calculation of polluting units. An application of a tax for each gas, applied per tonne of emission would be more straightforward, would make the price more salient, and would enable a better alignment of price levels with environmental costs and mitigation targets.

The current progressivity of rates as a function of a firm’s emissions is not aligned with environmental economic principles (in particular cost-efficiency). According to such principles, the tax schedules should be flat – i.e. have a single rate with no exemption threshold (but could depend on location for air pollution). The progressivity of rates might be to deal with affordability or equity considerations, by giving a minimum emission right to all installations and making each tonne of emission more costly above certain thresholds. However, equity and affordability concerns are best dealt with by complementary instruments providing support to firms, which can be direct or indirect. Indirect support could include a time-progressive phase in of base and rates. Direct support could include subsidies for green technology adoption. To ensure equity, subsidies could be tailored to firm size. Such measures are costly and could be implemented using the general budget or the revenue from green taxes (revenue recycling). Such measures could also help deal with competitiveness issues.

Given that GHG emissions are a global issue, the regional level may not be the most suitable governance level for regulation in this area. CO2 emissions in the industry and electricity sectors are already covered at the European level by the EU ETS and at the national level by fuel excise taxes. While the level of fuel excise taxes could be reformed to better align with benchmark carbon costs, this should be done at the national level.

Air pollutant emissions are principally a local issue, which makes them a suitable target for mitigation for regional level action. Current tax rates levied in Andalusia are on average similar to other rates observed in Spain and in the lower range when compared to other countries with similar taxes. This is useful for coordination with other Spanish Autonomous Communities but may be too low all the same to encourage enough abatement efforts. Having a better idea of target levels for SOx and NOx emission reductions as well as available mitigation technologies and costs could help adjust the price levels to reach such targets. If the objective is to reflect external costs for health in tax rates, Andalusia could consider including population density and pollution levels in the calculation of tax rates, similar to Chile. This would better align price levels with health and environmental costs (which are higher in more populated areas) and possibly discourage firms from settling in densely populated areas – where the negative impact of air pollution is higher – going forward.

An extension of the tax to PM emissions from industrial and electricity sector stationary sources could be considered. This would be relatively straightforward to implement given that NOx and SOx emissions are already taxed. Moreover, this would deal with one of the most harmful air pollutants for human health.

Finally, an extension of the tax to the farming sector would entail extending the coverage to other pollutants, such as NH3 and to other GHGs such as N2O and CH4 as well as adapting the emissions measurement methods to this sector. This would require dialogue and engagement with stakeholders, proposals for and existence of alternatives, possibility of measurement of farm-level emissions and support for farmers in the transition. Examples based on the New Zealand 2022 proposal for taxing farm-level emissions are exposed. Dialogue with farmers should also stress the benefits that better air quality and mitigated climate change would have on their sector and employees.

References

[54] Ainzúa et al. (2020), Capacity-building for the implementation of Chile’s green tax.

[17] Andalucia, J. (2021), Inventario de emisiones a la atmósfera de la Comunidad Autónoma de Andalucía. Serie 2003-2019.

[50] Andersen, M. and G. Bonnis (2021), “Climate mitigation co-benefits from sustainable nutrient management in agriculture: Incentives and opportunities”, OECD Environment Working Papers, No. 186, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://doi.org/10.1787/a2960c54-en.

[35] Anderson, B. (2021), “Policies for a climate-neutral industry: Lessons from the Netherlands”, OECD Science, Technology and Industry Policy Papers 108.

[18] Arneth, A. et al. (2009), “Clean the Air, Heat the Planet?”, Science, Vol. 326/5953, pp. 672-673, https://doi.org/10.1126/science.1181568.

[45] Bauer, S., K. Tsigaridis and R. Miller (2016), “Significant atmospheric aerosol pollution caused by world food cultivation”, Geophysical Research Letters, Vol. 43/10, pp. 5394-5400, https://doi.org/10.1002/2016gl068354.

[23] Boccanfuso, J. and A. Ferey (2021), Inattention and the taxation bias (Working paper).

[20] BOE, B. (2004), “Ley 18/2003, de 29 de diciembre” 26, https://www.boe.es/boe/dias/2004/01/30/pdfs/A03889-03925.pdf.

[21] Cañón-de-Francia, J., C. Garcés-Ayerbe and M. Ramírez-Alesón (2008), “Analysis of the effectiveness of the first European Pollutant Emission Register (EPER)”, Ecological Economics, Vol. 67/1, pp. 83-92, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2007.11.016.

[24] Chetty, R., A. Looney and K. Kroft (2009), “Salience and Taxation: Theory and Evidence”, American Economic Review, Vol. 99/4, pp. 1145-1177, https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.99.4.1145.

[33] D’Arcangelo, F. et al. (2022), “Estimating the CO2 emission and revenue effects of carbon pricing: New evidence from a large cross-country dataset”, OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No. 1732, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://doi.org/10.1787/39aa16d4-en.

[10] Dechezleprêtre, A., N. Rivers and B. Stadler (2019), “The economic cost of air pollution: Evidence from Europe”, OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No. 1584, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://doi.org/10.1787/56119490-en.

[12] Deryugina, T. et al. (2019), “The Mortality and Medical Costs of Air Pollution: Evidence from Changes in Wind Direction”, American Economic Review, Vol. 109/12, pp. 4178-4219, https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.20180279.

[40] Díaz-Robles, L. et al. (2011), “The Air Quality in Chile: Twenty Years of Challenge”, Environmental Management (EM), Air & Waste Management Association, Vol. 3.

[48] Dunkley, C. and K. Dunkley (2013), “Review - Greenhouse Gas Emissions from Livestock and Poultry”.

[56] European Commission (2021), “Ensuring that polluters pay - The Netherlands”.

[41] European Commission (2021), Proposal for a COUNCIL DIRECTIVE restructuring the Union framework for the taxation of energy products and electricity - COM(2021)563.

[22] European Commission (2017), “REFIT evaluation of Regulation (EC) No 166/2006 concerning the establishment of a European Pollutant Release and Transfer Register (E-PRTR)”, https://eur-lex.europa.eu/legal-content/EN/TXT/PDF/?uri=CELEX:52017SC0710&from=en.

[28] Flues, F. and K. van Dender (2020), “Carbon pricing design: Effectiveness, efficiency and feasibility: An investment perspective”, OECD Taxation Working Papers, No. 48, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://doi.org/10.1787/91ad6a1e-en.

[26] Flues, F. and K. van Dender (2017), “Permit allocation rules and investment incentives in emissions trading systems”, OECD Taxation Working Papers, No. 33, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://doi.org/10.1787/c3acf05e-en.

[52] García Bernal (2018), “Implementación del Impuesto Verde en Chile”.

[47] Herrero, E. et al. (2021), “Towards robust on-site ammonia emission measuring techniques based on inverse dispersion modeling”, Agricultural and Forest Meteorology, Vol. 307, p. 108517, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.agrformet.2021.108517.

[61] Hirst (2018), “Carbon Price Floor (CPF) and the price support mechanism”.

[63] Hirst, D. (2018), Carbon Price Floor (CPF) and the price support mechanism, https://researchbriefings.files.parliament.uk/documents/SN05927/SN05927.pdf.

[31] IEA (2021), Net Zero by 2050 - A Roadmap for the Global Energy Sector.

[62] IEA (2020), Extended world energy balances (database), https://doi.org/www.iea.org/statistics/topics/energybalances.

[43] INE (2023), Regional Accounts of Spain. Series 2016-2021..

[1] IPCC (2014), “IPCC, 2014: Climate Change 2014: Synthesis Report. Contribution of Working Groups I, II and III to the Fifth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change”, [Core Writing Team, R.K. Pachauri and L.A. Meyer (eds.)]. IPCC, Geneva, Switzerland, 151 pp, https://www.ipcc.ch/site/assets/uploads/2018/02/SYR_AR5_FINAL_full.pdf.

[44] Junta de Andalucia (2019), “Basic Environmental Data of Andalusia 2019”, http://www.juntadeandalucia.es/medioambiente/ddbb19.

[36] Juřík, R. and N. Braathen (2021), “Assessment of the air pollution tax and emission concentration limits in the Czech Republic”, OECD Environment Working Papers, No. 174, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://doi.org/10.1787/172ad5b9-en.

[30] Kaufman, N. et al. (2020), “A near-term to net zero alternative to the social cost of carbon for setting carbon prices”, Nature Climate Change, Vol. 10/11, pp. 1010-1014, https://doi.org/10.1038/s41558-020-0880-3.

[46] Lelieveld, J. et al. (2015), “The contribution of outdoor air pollution sources to premature mortality on a global scale”, Nature, Vol. 525/7569, pp. 367-371, https://doi.org/10.1038/nature15371.

[57] Leroutier (2022), “Carbon Pricing and Power Sector Decarbonization: Evidence from the UK”.

[34] Leroutier, M. (2022), “Carbon Pricing and Power Sector Decarbonisation: Evidence from the UK”, Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, Vol. 111, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jeem.2021.102580.

[11] Leroutier, M. and H. Ollivier (2022), “The Cost of Air Pollution for Workers and Firms”, Working Paper, https://marionleroutier.github.io/files/LeroutierOllivier_2022_cost_pollution_jmp.pdf.

[14] Lobell, D., S. Di Tommaso and J. Burney (2022), “Globally ubiquitous negative effects of nitrogen dioxide on crop growth”, Science Advances, Vol. 8/22, https://doi.org/10.1126/sciadv.abm9909.

[37] Mardones, C. and M. Cabello (2019), “Effectiveness of local air pollution and GHG taxes: The case of Chilean industrial sources”, Energy Economics, Vol. 83, pp. 491-500, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.eneco.2019.08.007.

[27] Martin, R. (2013), “Carbon markets, carbon prices and innovation: Evidence from interviews with managers.”, Paper presented at the Annual Meetings of the American Economic Association, San Diego..

[42] Millock, K. and C. Nauges (2003), “The French Tax on Air Pollution: Some Preliminary Results on its Effectiveness”, SSRN Electronic Journal, https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.419082.

[51] Ministry for the Environment and Ministry for Primary Industries (2022), Pricing agricultural emissions: Consultation document..

[13] Mink, J. (2022), “Putting a price tag on air pollution: the social healthcare costs of air pollution in France”, Working Paper.

[29] Mottershead, D. et al. (2021), Green taxation and other economic instruments. Internalising environmental costs to make the polluter pay, European Commission, Directorate-General for Environment, Brussels, https://environment.ec.europa.eu/publications/green-taxation-and-other-economic-instruments-internalising-environmental-costs-make-polluter-pay_en.

[32] Nordhaus, W. (2014), “Estimates of the Social Cost of Carbon: Concepts and Results from the DICE-2013R Model and Alternative Approaches”, Journal of the Association of Environmental and Resource Economists, Vol. 1/1/2, pp. 273-312, https://doi.org/10.1086/676035.

[7] OECD (2022), Air pollution effects (indicator), https://doi.org/10.1787/573e3faf-en (accessed on 29 November 2022).

[25] OECD (2022), Pricing Greenhouse Gas Emissions: Turning Climate Targets into Climate Action, OECD Series on Carbon Pricing and Energy Taxation, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://doi.org/10.1787/e9778969-en.

[4] OECD (2021), Effective Carbon Rates 2021: Pricing Carbon Emissions through Taxes and Emissions Trading, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://doi.org/10.1787/0e8e24f5-en.

[55] OECD (2021), Policies for a Carbon-Neutral Industry in the Netherlands, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://doi.org/10.1787/6813bf38-en.

[15] OECD (2020), Environment at a Glance 2020, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://doi.org/10.1787/4ea7d35f-en.

[5] OECD (2019), Taxing Energy Use 2019: Using Taxes for Climate Action, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://doi.org/10.1787/058ca239-en.

[6] OECD (2016), Effective Carbon Rates: Pricing CO2 through Taxes and Emissions Trading Systems, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://doi.org/10.1787/9789264260115-en.

[8] P.R. Shukla, J. (ed.) (2019), Annex I: Glossary, In Press, https://www.ipcc.ch/site/assets/uploads/2019/11/11_Annex-I-Glossary.pdf.

[49] Pan, S. et al. (2022), “Addressing nitrogenous gases from croplands toward low-emission agriculture”, npj Climate and Atmospheric Science, Vol. 5/1, https://doi.org/10.1038/s41612-022-00265-3.

[53] Pizarro (2019), Lessons from the Carbon Tax in Chile.

[39] Pizarro, R. (2019), https://greenfiscalpolicy.org/blog/environmental-fiscal-reform-in-chile-a-way-forward-for-developing-countries/.

[19] Portugal-Pereira, J. et al. (2018), “Interactions between global climate change strategies and local air pollution: lessons learnt from the expansion of the power sector in Brazil”, Climatic Change, Vol. 148/1-2, pp. 293-309, https://doi.org/10.1007/s10584-018-2193-3.

[38] Shapiro, J. and R. Walker (2018), “Why Is Pollution from US Manufacturing Declining? The Roles of Environmental Regulation, Productivity, and Trade”, American Economic Review, Vol. 108/12, pp. 3814-3854, https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.20151272.

[2] Spanish Ministry for Ecological Transition (2020), Nota informativa sobre el Avance de Emisiones de Gases de Efecto Invernadero correspondientes al año 2020.

[16] U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (2018), Technical Assistance Document for the Reporting of Daily Air Quality – the Air Quality Index (AQI).

[3] U.S. EPA Center for Corporate Climate Leadership (2016), Greenhouse Gas Inventory Guidance - Direct Emissions from Stationary Combustion Sources.

[60] United Kingdom government (2022), Participating in the UK ETS.

[59] United Kingdom government (2016), Carbon price floor.

[58] United Kingdom government (2016), “Climate Change Levy rates”.

[9] Zivin, J. and M. Neidell (2018), “Air pollution’s hidden impacts”, Science, Vol. 359/6371, pp. 39-40, https://doi.org/10.1126/science.aap7711.

This section presents selected case studies in the domain of greenhouse gas emissions and air pollution across the world with a focus on the industry and electricity sector

Notes

← 1. Cap-and-trade mechanisms should be understood as such.

← 2. Non-stationary sources refer to vehicles, which are covered in Section 4.

← 3. A gas’s radiative forcing can be understood as “the ability of a gas to absorb energy” and its lifetime as “how long they stay in the atmosphere”, see https://www.epa.gov/ghgemissions/understanding-global-warming-potentials, as accessed on 12 May 2022.

← 4. This period of 100 years is the most standard, but GWPs also exist for, e.g., 20 years.

← 5. Calorific factors from the IEA World Energy Statistics and Balances (IEA, 2020[62]) enable common units of fuels (e.g., kilograms for solid fuels, litres for liquid fuels, cubic metres for gaseous fuels) to be converted into energy units (e.g. GJ). In turn, these can then be converted into CO2 emissions using the IPCC emissions conversion factors (Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change’s Guidelines for National Greenhouse Gas Inventories (2019[8]), volume 2).

← 6. PMs are microscopic particles of solid or liquid matter suspended in the air. Some particles, such as dust, dirt, soot, or smoke, are sufficiently large or dark to be seen by eye. Others, such as PM10 or PM2.5 are not as visible. PM10 (resp. PM2.5) represent inhalable particles, with diameters that are generally 10 (2.5) micrometres and smaller.

← 7. https://www.who.int/news/item/25-03-2014-7-million-premature-deaths-annually-linked-to-air-pollution, as accessed on 29 November 2022.

← 8. See https://www.airnow.gov/aqi/aqi-basics/ (as accessed on 25 Januray 2023) for additional detail. In particular, “Good” stands for “Air quality is satisfactory, and air pollution poses little or no risk”, “Unhealthy” for “Some members of the general public may experience health effects; members of sensitive groups may experience more serious health effects” and “Hazardous” for “Health warning of emergency conditions: everyone is more likely to be affected”.

← 9. These figures are similar for PM10.

← 10. https://ec.europa.eu/environment/integration/research/newsalert/pdf/24si_en.pdf, as accessed on 12 May 2022.

← 11. As defined in the OECD effective carbon rates methodology (OECD, 2016[6]).

← 12. See BOE (2004[20]) or https://www.boe.es/buscar/act.php?id=BOE-A-2004-1739&p=20100809&tn=1&se-9, section 2, for additional detail. The webpage provides the possibility to access latest modifications to the legislation.

← 13. Direct GHG emissions are emissions from sources that are owned or controlled by the reporting entity. Indirect GHG emissions are emissions that are a consequence of the activities of the reporting entity, but occur at sources owned or controlled by another entity (https://ghgprotocol.org/calculationg-tools-faq).

← 14. Annex 1 of Law 16/2002 of July 1 provides a list of the fourteen activities covered. These refer to certain combustion installations, production and transformation of metals, mineral industries, chemical industries, waste management, industry derived from wood, textile industry, leather industry, agri-food industry and livestock farms, organic solvents, carbon industry, wood preservation industry, water treatment and capture of CO2.

← 15. Article 15 of BOE (2004[20]).

← 16. In 2018, it applied to 77 installations, and in 2020, to 66 installations.

← 17. Excluding CO2 emissions from the combustion of biofuels. This figure is of about 65% if including these emissions.

← 18. Andalusian firms subject to the EU ETS had average verified emissions of about 231 thousand tonnes of CO2, ranging between less than 10 and about 1.7 million tonnes. At the Spanish level, the average is at 139 thousand tonnes, ranging between 0 and about 5 million tonnes.

← 19. Information provided by the Tax Agency of Andalusia (ATRIAN).

← 20. 11https://www.hacienda.gob.es/es-ES/Prensa/En%20Portada/2014/Documents/Informe%20expertos.pdf

← 21. E.g., more effective in mitigating emissions.

← 22. E.g., if a justification were made that larger polluters should be made responsible for proportionally more of their emissions.

← 23. It also applies to emissions from aviation and to a very small share of emissions in the buildings sector, but this is not discussed here.

← 24. Other greenhouse gases are excluded from this analysis, as they constitute a minor part of emissions in these two sectors.

← 25. I.e., it does not include auto-generation of electricity in industrial plants.

← 26. https://tradingeconomics.com/commodity/carbon, as viewed on 21/07/2022. It is also worth noting that the price signal arising from the EU ETS in 2018 was much lower, at an average of EUR 16/tCO2.

← 27. Indeed, while not all biomass is carbon neutral, it can be. Taken at the point of combustion, biomass releases CO2. However, as discussed in OECD (2019[6]), sustainably sourced biomass may be carbon-neutral over the lifecycle because before being burnt, feedstocks have previously absorbed a similar amount of CO2 from the atmosphere.

← 28. See https://ember-climate.org/data/data-tools/carbon-price-viewer/, as accessed on 28 November 2022.

← 29. According to Table 3.1, the highest marginal rate is of 14 000 per unit of pollutant. Hence, at that marginal rate, one extra tonne of CO2 is equivalent to 1/200 000 polluting unit and is hence subject to a marginal rate of 14 000/200 000.

← 30. Such effects could also help go beyond the use of best available technologies promoted in Andalusia (https://eippcb.jrc.ec.europa.eu/es/reference). Indeed, the extensive margin effect would not be at play in the context of technology requirements only.

← 31. Agriculture made up 2.9% of Spanish GVA in 2021.

← 32. “A Major Source of Air Pollution: Farms – Global Study Shows How Agriculture Interacts with Industry”, https://www.earth.columbia.edu/articles/view/3281, as accessed on 29 November 2022.

← 33. See https://environment.govt.nz/news/consultaton-on-government-proposals-to-price-agricultural-greenhouse-gas-emissions/, as accessed on 08 November 2022.

← 34. See https://www.reuters.com/world/asia-pacific/new-zealand-farmers-protest-agricultural-emissions-plan-2022-10-20/, as accessed on 08 November 2022.

← 35. https://www.overseer.org.nz/, as accessed on 08 November 2022.

← 36. https://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2022-10-10/new-zealand-accepts-farm-level-pricing-of-agricultural-emissions, as accessed on 30 November 2022.

← 37. See https://www.realinstitutoelcano.org/en/work-document/taxation-and-ecological-transition-during-climate-and-energy-crises/ for a summary in English of the environmentally-related recommendations of the White Book.

Metadata, Legal and Rights

This document, as well as any data and map included herein, are without prejudice to the status of or sovereignty over any territory, to the delimitation of international frontiers and boundaries and to the name of any territory, city or area. Extracts from publications may be subject to additional disclaimers, which are set out in the complete version of the publication, available at the link provided.

© OECD 2023

The use of this work, whether digital or print, is governed by the Terms and Conditions to be found at https://www.oecd.org/termsandconditions.