4. From protest to participation

There is no end which the human will despairs of attaining through the combined power of individuals united into a society. (Tocqueville, 1960 [1835][1])

The coronavirus (COVID-19) pandemic is not yet over but there are already widespread calls for countries to “build back better” to meet the challenges they face today and will confront in the future. This chapter explores how this ambition can be realised at a moment when societies are so divided and capacity for collective action so weak. It argues that the project of building back better not only requires effective and widely-supported policies but also demands transformation of the institutional relationships between state, society, the economy and the environment. Indeed, it is not possible to separate one set of tasks from the other: only by identifying new approaches that engage and empower a broad range of citizens is it possible to formulate and implement an appropriate response to these challenges.

This chapter demonstrates how fostering engagement horizontally (across society) and vertically (between society and the state) can address the causes of discontent identified in this report. In so doing, it charts a way out of the development traps of low productivity, weak institutions and social vulnerability through approaches that emphasise the role of citizen participation. The chapter then sets out the importance of devising a collective vision for the future in which everyone can see their role and their route to a better life. It concludes by acknowledging some of the challenges that might impede these approaches, particularly in terms of financing.

The chapter affirms that promoting voice and agency among citizens is essential for reducing inequality and driving development. It envisages approaches to build back better from the ground up but contends this can only be achieved with appropriate and coordinated support across different levels of government. While the mechanisms outlined in this chapter seek to enhance well-being across all dimensions, they place particular emphasis on individuals’ social connections, civil engagement, knowledge and skills.

The first step in locating and strengthening society’s role in the development process is to set aside models predicated on individual economic agents in favour of paradigms that reflect the collective and plural nature of civil society. This entails a shift away from the narrow utilitarianism of Arrow (1951[2]) towards the multi-dimensional empowerment of Sen (1970[3]), whereby economic freedom is meaningless if not accompanied by social and political freedom. This section examines institutional and cultural factors behind development and how these interact to drive transformation. It then explores the concept of social capital as a means of capturing these dynamic interactions and as a basis for a stylised representation of the bonds that connect society and the state.

As defined by North, institutions are “humanly devised constraints that structure political, economic and social interaction”, and which can be either formal or informal (1991[4]). “History … is largely a story of institutional evolution in which the historical performance of economies can only be understood as a part of a sequential story. Institutions provide the incentive structure of an economy; as that structure evolves, it shapes the direction of economic change towards growth, stagnation, or decline.”

Acemoglu, Johnson and Robinson explain why economic institutions are such an important factor in determining a society’s development trajectory (2004[5]). They also recognise how the distribution of political power (both de jure and de facto) shapes the evolution of these institutions, reflecting the key role that political institutions play in economic development. They note how the distribution of resources within a society determines the design of political institutions, which raises the question of reverse causality, whereby economic growth affects the development of institutions. Of particular relevance to this report are the lessons they draw from how elites across history have voluntarily ceded some of their power – often to prevent unrest becoming revolution – by creating more inclusive political and economic institutions.

Culture, meanwhile, is a concept with a multitude of definitions not only across various sciences but also within them, reflecting the contestation around the term. A broad definition therefore seems judicious; the report characterises culture as a set of shared attitudes, values, goals and practices that depends on the capacity for learning and transmitting knowledge. Consistent with such a broad definition, culture can affect economic performance through many channels. For example, Weber, in one of the most influential studies of this phenomenon, examines the impact of religion on attitudes towards economic activity (1930 [1905][6]). Another channel is individuals’ propensity (or lack thereof) to trust and support each other and to share resources in addressing collective challenges.

Culture is also central to the framework laid out by Habermas, according to which the evolution of societies is driven by people’s capacity for rational communication, which in turn is fostered by a vibrant public sphere that encourages universal participation in all facets of social life (1981[7]). Amin and Thrift (2004[8]), meanwhile, demonstrate that culture and economy have become inseparable, a point implicitly acknowledged by Bourdieu (1984[9]), who argues that people’s social position and quality of life is determined by their economic, social and cultural capital (Pinxten and Lievens, 2014[10]).

As set out by Bisin and Verdier, institutions and culture are likely to interact and evolve together in fostering the co-operation on which development – and social cohesion – depend (2017[11]). Henrich explains how the cultural and institutional evolution of Western, educated, industrialised, rich and democratic (WEIRD) societies has produced a population that, in psychological terms, is an outlier from the rest of the global population across a number of variables, including individualistic tendencies, morality, capacity for co-operation and style of reasoning (2020[12]). It is possible or even likely that economic or social models that emerge from a WEIRD context will not function elsewhere. Meanwhile, advanced societies that were colonised by European powers in the middle centuries of the last millennium typically suffered a “Reversal of Fortune”, whereby their prosperity diminished significantly once a new set of institutions was imposed on it (Acemoglu, Johnson and Robinson, 2004[5]). For many of these countries, the imposition of economic and political institutions from outside has not stopped with decolonisation, as Chapter 5 discusses.

The relationship between culture and institutions might not always be straightforward. Where generalised trust does not exist in a society, strong institutions might emerge as essential mechanisms to ensure co-operation (Cook, Hardin and Levi, 2005[13]). Nor are the outcomes always positive. However, combining institutions and culture dynamically through the concept of social capital opens a space for elements such as political power and shared values into apparently intractable collective action problems – the vicious cycles (or development traps) – in ways not available to more technical approaches, where such elements are taken as given. Broadening the analytical framework opens up a larger set of possible mechanisms for resolving these issues.

Social capital is a cultural phenomenon with important institutional implications and is thus a useful mechanism for articulating the co-evolution of both. The concept of social capital and its application to development economics gained substantially in popularity during the 1990s. While challenges related to definition and measurement have since constrained its evolution, its importance is all too apparent in a world where atomisation and polarisation of societies are hindering collective action. This chapter argues that social capital is fundamental to social cohesion and should be regarded both as a key input and valuable outcome of public policies.

Woolcock and Narayan define social capital as “the norms and networks that enable people to act collectively” (2000[14]). The transformative potential of social capital is possessed by individuals and groups and covers all spheres of life, including social, economic and political. It fosters the tendency to trust both within and between groups, and between civil society and the state. As Fukuyama puts it, “[an] abundant stock of social capital is presumably what produces a dense civil society, which in turn has been almost universally seen as a necessary condition for modern liberal democracy” (1999[15]).

Social capital has the potential to address the two main sources of discontent. As mentioned in Chapter 3, it underpins the relationships that support individuals trying to make their way in modern society and the networks of trust, reciprocity and interdependence that hold societies together. At the same time, numerous studies have shown that social capital is essential for achieving broad-based and sustained improvements in living standards (World Bank, 2001[16]). Although typically omitted from standard economic models, social capital generates the intangible phenomena that underpin development: the trust, relationships, co-operation, organisational skills and know-how essential for problem solving, innovation and expansion. As Dasgupta and Serageldin state, “social capital…draws our attention to those particular institutions serving economic life that might otherwise go unnoted” (1999[17]).

There are important qualifications to make about social capital, starting with inevitable issues of definition and measurement for what is an abstract concept. Trust, participation, and strength of civic institutions often feature in attempts to quantify social capital but there lacks an empirical consensus. Indeed, some argue that the very term “capital” is inaccurate. Even if there were a specific measure, it is impossible to define an appropriate time frame for analysis: social capital evolves as societies evolve.

Social capital can also empower groups that do considerable harm: criminal gangs and the perpetrators of ethnic violence might possess strong social capital (ERIC, IDESO, IDIES, IUDOP, 2004[18]), (Colletta and Cullen, 2000[19]). While some have argued that social capital is a public good, others see it as a mechanism for exclusion: Bourdieu explains how it allows upper social classes to retain their status (1980[20]). Putnam has been criticised for linking the deterioration of democracy in the United States to a decline in social capital due to its focus on the individual (1995[21]). This places the onus on individuals to develop their own social capital by joining an association or becoming more active in the community; the state’s responsibility to reduce economic and social inequality implicitly falls away (Ferragina and Arrigoni, 2017[22]). Another concern is that the term implies a rivalrous relationship with the state, suggesting that its reach into private relations jeopardises – or might be resisted by – the natural functioning of society.

This chapter employs the framework described by the World Bank, according to which social capital can be bonding, bridging or linking (2001[16]). Bonding capital captures an individual’s close ties with their immediate network of family or local community, while bridging capital brings an individual (or group) into contact with other groups. They are thus brought into civil society: associational life predicated on active engagement across a plurality of shared interests that forms the “third sector” of society, distinct from big business and the state. Linking capital allows civil society to interact with power as articulated by the state.

Interactions at the meso level are particularly important for addressing discontent and are thus of central concern to this report. Secondary institutions serve as interlocutors between the individual and the state, allowing the grievances of a particular constituency to be expressed to an institution empowered to address them. Where these interlocutors interact regularly with the state, sudden outbursts of discontent are less likely to occur, and there is greater likelihood of addressing the more structural causes of discontent.

The state has a critical role to play in fostering and harnessing social capital. As Woolcock and Narayan contend, “[the] state is the actor best able to facilitate enduring alliances across the boundaries of class, ethnicity, race, gender, politics, and religion” (2000[14]). This chapter explains how these alliances can be mobilised through participatory processes to strengthen governance, vitalise political processes and generate innovation in public and private spheres. Such processes address the decline in institutional trust identified this report by facilitating productive interactions between state and civil society and by improving development outcomes.

These forms of social capital are represented in Figure 4.1, a simple pyramidal representation of society and state that captures the micro, meso and macro levels on which social capital operates and the various flows of social capital. These levels are not exclusive: at a basic level, an individual might be part of a household, fulfil an active role in civil society and be employed by a public institution. Nonetheless, this stylised model, on which this chapter builds, demonstrates the role each level plays in social, economic and political life, and the mechanics of inclusion and exclusion. The upward arrows from bridging and linking social capital convey agency and voice; the downward arrows from public institutions indicate the capacity of the state to empower. Sideways arrows between institutions demonstrate co-operation. It should be noted, however, that the pyramid could be rotated to reflect that the state’s power ultimately flows from its citizens, as per Rousseau (1762[23]).

The size of the uppermost pyramid – the state – can vary, although it does not do so in this chapter. Such variation would depict the amount of space in which civil society can operate rather than ‘the size of government’ in an economic sense. A large state may be understood as constraining the space available to civil society by restricting freedom of association, peaceful assembly and expression – elements often linked to the health of a democracy itself, as discussed in Chapter 2. CIVICUS reports that the space for civil society had been narrowing in many countries in recent years and that this trend accelerated during the COVID-19 pandemic (2020[24]). However, it also finds that 2019 was a year of extensive civil society mobilisation across the world around a number of national and global challenges, which was able to achieve real change.

Individual households and small communities within a society along the bottom of the triangle (usually) possess bonding capital. Bridging capital allows individuals from these units to interact with secondary institutions – a highly diverse array of larger groups ranging from small firms and labour unions to churches and sport clubs. Individuals can belong to any number of associations, and these associations can interact with each other to create the “dense network” mentioned above. Above the secondary institutions are public institutions, such as the board of education that interacts with a parent-teacher association or the chamber of commerce that works with local businesses. These are examples of complementary linking, as shown by the arrows running in both directions. The importance of horizontal as well as vertical flows within this model requires a broad understanding of the social contract (Box 4.1).

This chapter uses the stylised societal framework introduced in the previous section to address the challenges outlined in Chapters 2 and 3. To do so, the framework first adds an additional layer of institutions: the large firms, or clusters of firms, that are displayed above the small firms in a stylised version of an economy with full employment (Figure 4.2). Small firms are considered part of civil society, rooted as they are in a community, both spatially and culturally. The larger firms, including multinational enterprises are not; these firms might be expected to cluster in particular locations (normally major cities) and have weak links to a particular community. The representation reflects these differences in proximity to households, which are now ranged along the bottom of the pyramid left to right according to income, with the lowest income households at the far left.

The public institutions depicted in Figure 4.1 are replaced by economic institutions in Figure 4.2. These institutions include the agencies established to promote economic development through the provision of infrastructure, direct support for enterprises, research and development activities or higher education as well as a stable macroeconomic framework and the rights and regulations that govern the conduct of firms. These are “promotive institutions”. Economic institutions also incorporate regulations designed to protect workers and the environment from the potential excesses of economic life, which the chapter terms “protective institutions”. These include laws governing maximum working hours or minimum wages, the freedom to form trade unions and social security systems.

Polanyi considered these promotive and protective institutions as constituting a “double movement” (2001 [1944][29]). Capitalist states facilitate the free functioning of the market economy while responding to the demands of society for protection from the associated adverse social and environmental consequences. In this way, the economy remains embedded within social relations despite pursuing its own logic. When protective institutions weaken, the economy becomes disembedded from society; instead, “social relations are embedded in the economy”, and social institutions are divided into the economic and the political (with the latter unable to affect the former). In an idea with powerful resonance today, Polanyi considered that citizens would find intolerable a situation whereby they are unable to exercise control over the economy while having no choice but to participate in it, even on terms that violate their notions of justice or dignity.

Civil society has a critical role to play both as a counterweight to the state and in protecting the individual from the state. However, civil society is also a locus for contestation and dominance, with its own hierarchy. It contains elites, disaffected middle classes and different factions of the precariat, and it produces political parties of opposing ideologies. These elements are the lifeblood of politics but where political systems are dysfunctional, civil society can be captured by powerful sectoral interests that undermine Polanyi’s second movement.

Gramsci recognised the hierarchies within civil society, which he saw to be both economic-political and cultural and ideational (Brighenti, 2016[30]). In spite of its plurality, he argued that civil society in democratic societies tends to be locked into a set of power relations directed by a specific way of thinking; this tendency not only allows inequality to reproduce itself but also prevents the emergence and adoption of new ideas even when the existing paradigm is increasingly discredited. In this context, an innovative political project gains traction through its currency with people’s everyday realities rather than through a revolution directed at the state. Radical change must be fostered by the democratic institutions within civil society.

Polanyi recognised that economic development is a partnership between public and private institutions (2001 [1944][29]). As this model illustrates, firms would not be able to operate, much less thrive, without the support of public institutions. Virtuous circles of reciprocity can develop between firms and economic institutions. While firms benefit from economic institutions, the institutions (and the state more broadly) benefit from engagement with firms: by monitoring the performance of firms, public institutions gain a better understanding of the economy, which in turn allows them to optimise their involvement in the future. Meanwhile, successful firms generate higher revenues for the government through taxes on their profits.

The links between firms, other secondary institutions and households are critical for embedding the economy. These links are not solely commercial: at an individual level, the status conferred by a certain profession or position might greatly enhance an individual’s standing in the wider community. Labour unions and employee organisations might be highly active in non-professional activities: the exalted Indian Railways cricket team leaps to mind. The links between firms and the community create a space for overview of the economy (at least at a local level) and thus an allocation of responsibility to individual actors for any damage they might inflict on society or the environment.

A key feature of this stylised model is its universality: all firms are in the formal economy and everyone is employed. The economy generates public revenues, which in turn finance further investment in the economy and the provision of high-quality public services. Social security is largely financed through contributions by workers and their employers but sufficient public funds exist to redistribute resources to vulnerable groups outside the labour market through a range of social services. Moreover, a citizenry with extensive social capital generates a dense civil society, which is in close contact with the state, thus strengthening social cohesion and collective action. In the sections that follow, the model illustrates how this virtuous circle breaks down in contexts of social, economic and political fragmentation and polarisation.

This section builds on the stylised model developed in this chapter to address the three development traps mentioned in Chapter 2 related to low productivity, weak public institutions and the vulnerability of citizens. In each case, it outlines approaches that enhance individual well-being across multiple dimensions while improving economic outcomes for society as a whole, at the same time as they foster social cohesion and strengthen the bonds between society and the state.

Chapter 2 explains the productivity trap facing developing countries in terms of undiversified economies with low levels of productivity and large informal sectors. Many developing economies rely on exports from primary sectors with low levels of sophistication (such as mining or agriculture) and are unable to support the growth of micro, small and medium-sized enterprises (MSMEs), even though these account for the vast majority of firms. In Latin America, for example, MSMEs account for 99.5% of firms (with firms at the micro level alone accounting for 88.4%) and 61.0% of employment but only 24.5% of production (OECD/CAF/ECLAC/EU, 2019[31]).

While there are numerous facets to the productivity trap, this chapter focuses on the small size and low productivity of firms. Returning to the stylised model, Figure 4.3 depicts an economy operating some distance from its potential. It introduces a dividing line (henceforth, the “red line”) between what might be considered in crude terms as the modern, productive or efficient part of the economy on the right and the untransformed, unproductive or informal part of the economy on the left. The institutions either side of the red line operate within the same society; there are no cultural or legal impediments to firms or households crossing from one side to the other. However, the differences in the institutional landscape on each side indicate that the firms on the left-hand side are poorly linked to each other and to large firms, and they have little or no role or voice in the productive or formal economy.

In this stylised model, only firms and workers on the right-hand side of the dividing line are covered by promotive and protective institutions. There are no large firms operating in the left-hand triangle, but small firms operate on both sides (and, one assumes, interact in this space). The red line represents the barriers that informal firms (which we expect account for the majority of enterprises on the left-hand side) face in seeking to join the formal sector or to integrate themselves in the value chains of large firms. These barriers might be related to finance, skills or competitiveness, but they might also pertain to the broader economic context. Households working for firms on the left-hand side are shaded in grey on the understanding that their status is closely linked to that of their livelihood.

The red line reflects policy choices that have benefited certain groups at the expense of others or have set the economy on a particular path. These choices might have been made many years ago, notably in the case of former colonies whose economies were engineered to fulfil a particular need for the benefit of a colonial power. This is particularly the case with extractive colonial models (Acemoglu, Johnson and Robinson, 2004[5]). However, the choices might also reflect the power and interests of particular domestic groups that influence policy making today. Most notable in this context are the links between economic development and state formation mentioned earlier: the capitalist state and those who exercise power within this state are often invested in a particular model that grants them financial resources and political control. These structural dynamics hardwire inequality into an economic system and economic policy, and they prevent mechanisms of supply and demand from equalising firms and individuals.

The ranging of households at the bottom of the triangle by income is imperfect. People working in the informal economy can earn large sums of money, while productive firms (small and large) require workers at various income levels, who might be fully covered by protective institutions as a result. However, in aggregate, it seems reasonable to assume that the precariat discussed in Chapter 1, trapped in unproductive activities and highly vulnerable across a number of dimensions, are to the left of the line. This is a source of discontent for them and a waste of human resources for society as a whole.

This divided model recalls the dualist theories of economic development. In broad terms, these distinguish between traditional and modern sectors of a developing economy, as well as between the primary and secondary labour markets associated with these sectors. Many theorists expect that, over time, economic forces, particularly technology, will destroy the traditional sector, leaving in place a homogenised modern economy. Berger and Piore contest this interpretation, demonstrating not only that traditional firms co-exist with modern firms but also that modern firms support the traditional sector (as happens in France and Italy, for example) (1980[32]). Moreover, traditional firms might even be able to expand and thrive.

In explaining this phenomenon, Berger and Piore (1980[32]) and Brusco and Sabel (1981[33]) demonstrate how small firms might prosper in a modernising economy. They argue that traditional firms might diffuse the products of the larger firms, large firms might contract with traditional firms to deal with fluctuations in demand and traditional firms might be better suited to certain tasks. They also show that cultural factors might generate strong social support for traditional enterprises, which incentivises governments to support the traditional sector through subsidies or trade protection for political gain. Rather than be left behind by large firms, traditional firms can exploit their role vis-à-vis the modern sector to innovate and expand.

The divided model can also capture geographical disparities in productivity, with less productive regions on the left-hand side and more productive on the right. This permits the exploration of territorial approaches to development, notably those originating from the district model outlined by Marshall, which focuses on the capacity of local areas to generate productivity gains endogenously (1879[34]). “Each man profits by the ideas of his neighbours: he is stimulated by contact with those who are interested in his own pursuit to make new experiments; and each successful invention, whether it be a new machine, a new process, or a new way of organizing the business is likely when once started to spread and to be improved upon”. Becattini (2017[35]) and Brusco (1982[36]) explain how small firms might expand under a Marshallian approach in which they co-operate with other small firms on product upgrading and innovation; as a result, they become competitive with large, vertically integrated firms.

Social capital allows traditional firms to organise themselves differently to large firms. Under a Marshallian logic, small firms can coexist with large firms based not on their efficiency or their market power but on the relationships they generate with other small firms, with large firms and with society as a whole. These relationships are based on trust and goodwill, cultural factors generated by repeated interactions and reciprocity that reduce transaction costs. As Lin and Nugent argue, transaction costs – including the direct costs of obtaining information, negotiating contracts and communicating with partners, and the indirect costs of monitoring these arrangements – play a key role in shaping institutions (1995[37]).

The decentralised, bottom-up approaches to industrial development outlined here contrast with the centralised top-down archetype of industrial policy. They build not only on the mutually advantageous relationships that small firms can foster both each other and with large firms but also on the cultural ties that embed smaller firms within a given community. This rootedness is a source of political power that firms can exploit to gain support from the economic institutions of the state. In this way, the gap Polanyi identified between the political and economic spheres is narrowed, allowing civil society greater influence.

These approaches involve each level of the stylised model in a dynamic set of interactions whose parameters are established partly by the market, partly by society and partly by the political system, in other words, a symbiosis of culture and institutions. As Marshall puts it, “the secrets of industry are in the air”, to be captured through “conviviality” and “face-to-face” interactions (1879[34]). The rise of teleworking during the COVID-19 pandemic might have implications in this regard.

Echoing Marshall’s argument, Andrews finds patents declined significantly in counties in the United States where prohibition laws passed from 1917-19 forced the closure of bars and other drinking establishments, an ountcome he attributes to a tendency for informal interactions outside the workplace to facilitate invention by encouraging collaboration and the sharing of ideas (2019[38]). The author finds that patent numbers in these counties recovered after three years as people reconfigured their social networks and that these new configurations were reflected in changes in the technological classes of the patents. Meanwhile, Box 4.2 explains how another facet of social capital – the “know-how” located within networks – can be just as important as knowledge.

In this example, a benign combination of institutional and cultural factors and policy choices can shift the red line leftwards to make the productive economy more inclusive. The example also demonstrates that it is not possible to move the line leftwards by applying pressure at a single point; rather, initiatives must push in a co-ordinated fashion along its length. From the perspective of the government, policies to promote the development of MSMEs must be aligned from the micro to the macro level, from exchange rates to local infrastructure, for example.

The model assumes that all individuals have full and equal access to the state insofar as they enjoy equal rights as regards voting and citizenship. This is represented by the pendulum pivoting at the bottom of the inner green triangle rather than the top. However, it does not imply equal access to public institutions or an adequate equitable provision of services, as the next section discusses.

The institutional trap is a key ingredient of today’s discontent. It is premised on the growing expectations of emerging middle classes, whose members aspire to a better life for themselves and their children and, as a result, demand better public services, in particular education and health. Middle-class status means that these individuals might be paying tax on their income for the first time and are thus even more sensitive to the quality of the services they are financing. If they are not satisfied, they lose the incentive to pay tax; lower tax revenues imply lower-quality services, and a vicious circle develops that can result in civil unrest.

Recent work on tax morale finds evidence of this vicious cycle in some countries but not others. The OECD shows tax morale to be higher in the OECD and Latin America than in Africa and Eastern Europe (2019[41]). However, the situation seems to be improving in Africa and deteriorating in Latin America. The proportion of people who strongly agreed that the government has the right to make people pay taxes rose sharply in Africa between 2005 and 2015: by the end of this period, only one-quarter of the population disagreed with this government right, although there is evidence that the upwards trajectory stalled or even reversed subsequently (Isbell and Olan’g, 2021[42]). In Latin America, the proportion of individuals who believed that it is justifiable to cheat on one’s taxes rose between 2011 and 2015; by the latter year, less than half of respondents thought that it was never justifiable to do so (OECD, 2019[41]).

The OECD identifies clear trends among the varying attitudes to taxation (2019[41]). More educated individuals view paying taxes more positively; women generally have higher tax morale (although not in Africa); older people are less likely to justify cheating on taxes; and people who claim a faith or religious identity are more in favour of paying taxes. Institutional factors also matter: individuals who believe that they are living in a meritocratic society have significantly higher tax morale, as do people who trust the government, support redistribution or consider democracy to be the best form of government. These results are complemented by the work of Andriani et al. on the cultural factors behind tax morale (2021[43]). Based on the evolution of tax morale in 48 countries over 30 years, they find that political inequality (what they term “power distance”) and a lack of transparency in government operations tend to interact with people’s deeply held values to reduce the likelihood of tax compliance.

Developing countries can ill-afford weak tax compliance. Figure 4.4 demonstrates the financial constraints many developing countries face relative to OECD economies when attempting to satisfy the demands of a growing middle class. Harmonised tax data for more than 100 countries shows how much these revenues vary across countries and regions (OECD, 2021[44]). The average tax-to-gross domestic product (GDP) ratio for OECD economies in 2018 was 34.3%; in Latin America and the Caribbean (LAC), it was 23.1%, and in Africa, it was 16.5%. These averages mask significant within-region variation. LAC’s tax-to-GDP ratios ranged from 13.2% in Dominican Republic and Guatemala to 42.3% in Cuba. In Africa, they ranged from 6.3% in Equatorial Guinea and Nigeria to 32.4% in the Seychelles (OECD, AUC and ATAF, 2020[45]). A regional average for the Asia Pacific region is not available, but average tax-to-GDP ratios ranged from 11.9% in Indonesia to 35.4% in Nauru (OECD, 2020[46]). Over the period 2009-18, the gap between the Africa and LAC averages and the OECD average hardly narrowed.

These trends demonstrate the fiscal challenge facing governments in developing countries as they look to improve public services. Assuming that the majority of tax revenues (especially from taxes on income and profits) are generated by the productive part of the economy to the right of the red line in Figure 4.3, it follows that the smaller the right-hand triangle, the lower these revenues are likely to be and the less they can afford to spend on services for the wider population. Unless a country follows an inclusive development path – one that expands the tax base by increasing the number of firms and individuals operating in the productive part of the economy – the government might well lack the financing required to expand and improve public services at a rate that satisfies the population. This is compounded by the challenge of sustaining the quality of services while scaling them up: intuitively, it takes one or more generations of quality schooling to produce a nationwide supply of good teachers and doctors. Citizens’ expectations might not tolerate such a lag

Charting a way out of the institutional trap requires a deeper understanding – and harnessing – of the role secondary institutions can play in getting the most out of public spending, especially in constrained fiscal contexts. While tax morale partly reflects an individual’s attitude towards the state (in particular, whether they feel they are getting out of the fiscal system what they put in), improving tax morale and strengthening public services depends in large part on the intermediary institutions located between citizens and the state.

Middle-class taxpayers unhappy with the quality of their children’s education, for example, must choose between two courses of action when faced with poor public services: they can continue to use services while pushing for improvement or they can go to the private sector for their health and education needs. These two responses might have very different impacts on the long-term prospects of the service in question, as outlined by Hirschman, who characterises them as a choice between “exit” and “voice” (1972[47]). If the parents send their children to private school, this will do nothing to improve the quality of public provision; however, if they use their voice to express dissatisfaction with a school, they might achieve something. Assuming these are relatively well-off individuals who are likely to be endowed with significant social capital, both in the sense that they have the capacity to influence various groups and in terms of the tacit knowledge that they possess which might help the school to address some of the challenges it faces.

The question for the government is how to give voice to these parents. A parent-teacher association establishes a two-way dialogue between individuals and a public institution through which complaints can be aired and discussed. A governing board comprising parents and other members of the community can oversee a school’s performance. An education board or local department of education can liaise with these institutions to ensure higher-level involvement and, where necessary, remedial action. These are examples of bridging and linking social capital.

Two factors are important here: opportunities for voice and the power to effect change. Both are critical to the participatory approaches to public services that are increasingly recognised as prerequisite for their effectiveness. Rosanvallon argues that this trend reflects changes in the nature of democratic systems, where “the inability of electoral/representative politics to keep its promises (has) led to the development of indirect forms of democracy” (2008[48]). Citizens are represented (and are exercising) power beyond the ballot box through their capacity for oversight (surveillance), prevention (capacity to protest) and judgment (power to take the government to court). Through these mechanisms, civil society serves as custodian for public goods, ensuring both their quality and their broad accessibility.

The three dimensions of counter-democracy – and the institutions that underpin them – need to be operational simultaneously if governments are to be held to account. They also need to operate across the economic, social and environmental spheres to ensure a broad range of rights is protected. Voice without power is merely consultation, and where consultation does not lead to change, citizens are likely to lose interest in or even resent the process. Mechanisms by which citizens can provide feedback about the quality of public services are a more complex case: their voice is an important source of accountability for public officials and has the power to improve public services, but it positions citizens as consumers of public services rather than giving them an active role in improving matters. On the other hand, participatory budgeting has the potential to improve public services and institutionalises the power of citizens (Box 4.3).

Without the power to effect change, it is unlikely the parents in this example will keep their children in the public system unless compelled to do so. This compulsion might take two forms. The first is societal: it might be culturally frowned upon to opt out of public schools because it is incumbent on everyone to support the system. These cultural factors exercise great influence over people’s behaviour, and (although not discussed here) they are closely linked to social capital. The second mechanism is to exclude rival service providers. This is not easy to do in a market economy but can nonetheless be critical to the sustainability of a public system. Many health systems, for example, have clear rules about which services can be provided by the private and public sectors. Security is another example where this might be necessary: if private security services expand beyond a certain degree, the state no longer has a monopoly on law and order provision or even the use of violence.

Keeping these parents engaged with the school and empowering them to improve its performance has the potential to create a virtuous circle. Not only do they continue to attend and continue to pay taxes because of this improvement, but other parents are more likely to do so as well. The resultant increase in revenues allows further improvements in quality, alleviating the discontent that poor public services often generate. All the while, children at the school receive better teaching and emerge as more productive members of society.

This has the potential to move the red line to the left but, as mentioned above, only if it is accompanied by other interventions higher up. No matter how well-taught children might be, if there is no chance of them finding productive employment once they leave school, the economic returns on education will be minimal and the incentive to enrol children similarly low. In this way, escaping the institutional trap is conditional on progress in escaping the productivity trap.

The institutional trap can compound the productivity trap. Where economic activity is relatively concentrated and the government is thus reliant on a relatively small number of firms to finance public services, these firms enjoy significant bargaining power which they can use to lobby against attempts to regulate or diversify the economy. At the very least, this influence can generate a degree of risk aversion in governments; at worst, it can prompt governments to introduce policies that empower incumbents and increase barriers to entry.

This examination of the institutional trap prompts two final points about the purpose of education that are germane for this report. First, education is a key route to freedom at an individual level, provided that it challenges structural power dynamics (Freire, 1970[49]); at a societal level, it can serve as a mechanism for generating what Unger calls a “social imagination” to craft alternative visions of the future beyond prevailing, unsustainable models (2009[50]). Both Freire and Unger recognise the importance of education in encouraging critical thought, problem solving, co-operation and dialogue rather than a top-down flow of information if education is to achieve its transformational potential. Second (and relatedly), education has the capacity to inculcate a sense of civic responsibility that has the potential not only to enhance social cohesion but also to generate the level of citizen engagement essential for the more participatory approaches to democracy discussed in this chapter (OECD, 2017[51]).

The social vulnerability trap articulates the reality of citizens who are classified as middle class in terms of their income but whose status is fragile. Individuals caught in the social vulnerability trap are typically in informal, low-quality, low-paying jobs without social protection coverage. They find it difficult to accumulate the savings required to invest either in themselves (through further training) or in an enterprise and are highly susceptible to income shocks, which can push them back into poverty. Their mobility is limited; although they might change jobs relatively often, they will usually move from one informal job to another. These citizens have been hit especially hard by the COVID-19 pandemic. This vulnerable population is located along the bottom of the left-hand triangle of this chapter’s stylised model but is unlikely to be at the far left, where individuals who remain in poverty are located.

This chapter explores the social vulnerability trap through the lens of social protection – the broad set of policies and programmes designed to alleviate poverty and protect individuals and their households from risks over the entire course of their life. As of May 2021, 222 countries and territories had scaled up social protection provision in response to the COVID-19 pandemic, underlining its importance as an economic and social stabiliser in times of crisis (Gentilini et al., 2021[59]). Social protection also has a key role to play in helping countries to recover from the pandemic in the short term and to build back better in the long term. Consistent with the approaches to the other development traps outlined in this chapter, enhancing social protection simultaneously achieves better outcomes for individuals while also strengthening social cohesion and reinforcing the social contract.

Demonstrating the importance of social protection to social cohesion, Alik-Lagrange et al. explain that social protection affect relations between society and the state through three channels: the redistributive, the contractual and the reconstitutive (2021[60]). The redistributive channel captures what governments provide to citizens, the contractual channel reflects what citizens expect from the government and how they perceive the state’s authority, and the reconstitutive channel captures how states and citizens see themselves and each other. The authors explain how these channels are affected by the design of social protection programmes as well as by their financing modalities, and they emphasise that the interactions between programme and context have a significant impact on an intervention’s effectiveness.

Social protection not only provides the income support required to get people out of or stop them falling into poverty; it is also a critical means of enhancing social inclusion and social cohesion. As Babajanian and Hagen-Zanker explain, social protection establishes legal rights for citizens, can improve human capabilities or human capital, and can enable poor and vulnerable people to strengthen their assets, all of which promote their inclusion in different facets of daily life (2012[61]). In the case of social cohesion, Babajanian argues that social protection can “improve intergroup solidarity, tackle discrimination and stigma, reduce or prevent social conflicts, and achieve greater stability” (2012[62]).

De Milliano et al. demonstrate how these positive impacts of social protection come together Ghana’s Livelihood Empowerment Against Poverty (LEAP) 1000, a cash transfer programme for pregnant women and mothers of young children living in poverty (2021[63]). The authors find that women participating in LEAP 1000 were more likely to receive social support than a control group and no less likely to receive financial support. Moreover, the study finds that LEAP 1000 beneficiaries were more likely to participate in community groups and that their access to financial markets, such as borrowing money or contributing to local savings schemes, had improved. These findings rebut the theory that social protection programmes weaken social support networks by “crowding out” the informal support of friends and neighbours; rather, the authors find evidence that social protection “crowds in” community support.

The COVID-19 pandemic has demonstrated the importance of universal provision of social protection, as articulated by Sustainable Development Goal 1.3. However, as Chapter 1 shows, that less than 50% of the world’s population has access to one social protection programme, with coverage in Africa, the Arab States and Asia Pacific typically far below this level. Coverage among vulnerable middle-class members (especially those of working age) on whom this chapter focuses is often particularly low: because they are not considered to be among the extreme poor and typically do not fall within a vulnerable group (such as the elderly or people with disabilities), they are unlikely to be eligible for a tax-financed social assistance programme. At the same time, their informal status and irregular income means that they are unlikely to be covered by a social insurance arrangement. They therefore form part of what can be termed the “missing middle” of social protection coverage.

Viewed in narrow, technical terms, the missing middle phenomenon is an intractable problem. Governments in developing countries typically generate a much lower level of tax revenues than advanced economies and thus, it is assumed, are unable to expand social assistance. Meanwhile, efforts to expand social insurance arrangements to workers on low and irregular salaries raise concerns that contributions will increase the cost of labour and thus undermine efforts to increase formalisation in the economy (OECD/IDB/CIAT, 2016[64]). Various options have been attempted to combine social assistance and social insurance through partial public subsidies (which translate into lower contribution or tax rates). These have had limited success in increasing coverage, for example in the case of combined contributions in Latin American pension systems (Bosch, Melguizo and Pagés, 2013[65]). In other cases, the subsidies have cost the fiscus more than expected, as is the case with Indonesia’s Jaminan Kesehatan Nasional health insurance scheme, which has nonetheless achieved rapid success in improving coverage across the informal economy and moving towards universal health coverage more broadly (OECD, 2019[66]).

Informality is the common denominator in the missing middle problem. It is a constraint to social insurance coverage (which is typically predicated on formal labour relations) and it restricts the size of the tax base, thereby limiting the potential for domestic resource mobilisation that can finance non-contributory social assistance. It is not just the lack of visibility of the informal labour force that constrains policies to expand social protection to this group; its heterogeneity is also a major challenge. For example, not all workers in the informal economy have low and irregular incomes; they are often able to contribute something. They are often in some form of regular employment relationship (as part of a formal enterprise’s supply chain, for example), and there is therefore an employer who could contribute to their income security. Moreover, an informal worker might still be covered by social insurance through a member of their household. Better understanding these specificities is an important first step towards understanding the social realities of informality (OECD/ILO, 2019[67]).

A universal approach to social protection is the best and only solution to the missing middle problem and to the social vulnerability trap more broadly. As explained by Packard et al., social protection systems that are not adapted to high levels of informality in developing countries or to the changing nature of work in advanced economies render vulnerable a large portion of the workforce and greatly constrain risk-sharing across the population (2019[68]). The authors call for a major expansion of social assistance beyond poverty targeting (moving coverage ‘up’ the income distribution) to protect vulnerable workers from falling into poverty when large-scale risks materialise. This should be co-ordinated with an expansion of social insurance arrangements ‘down’ the income distribution that shares risk and financing responsibilities fairly between individuals, employers (where a labour relationship exists) and the state. At the same time, expansion of well-regulated and flexible voluntary savings and insurance arrangements for workers at all income levels would respond to the fluidity and diversity of people’s employment activities, as well as the associated income variability (Packard et al., 2019[68]).

The push for universal social protection in developing countries must overcome certain preconceptions. The first is that a country’s income level determines whether it can scale up social protection. European countries introduced universal social pensions at an early stage of their development, when their per capita incomes were equivalent to the level in Latin America in the 1980s and 1990s, and tax revenues as a percentage of GDP were far lower than they are today. South Korea committed to universal health coverage at an early point in its economic development. As Mkandawire states, “[social] policies have served not only as an instrument of development, but also as a guarantee that the development process will ensure, contemporaneously, the wide range of ‘ends’ of development and nation-building” (2005[69]). This process can also work in reverse: Kyrgyzstan has sustained universal pension coverage since the collapse of the Soviet Union, despite a massive economic contraction (OECD, 2018[70]).

The second preconception is that the Global South has always been playing catch up on social protection towards an idealised vision of the European-style welfare state. In fact, as Wehr, Leubolt and Schaffar point out, “a considerable number of states in the Global South, especially in parts of Asia and Latin America, developed modern welfare state policies and structures at the same time or even earlier than most of the European countries” (2015[71]). In developing countries across Africa, Asia and Latin America, especially those that pursued import substitution policies, social security was an important part of the social contract and the project of state building, albeit one that benefited a relatively small constituency that tended to be urban, middle class and politically powerful (Mesa-Lago, 1978[72]), (OECD, 2020[73]). Oscillations between authoritarianism and democracy also played their part, as “welfare state policies were used to alleviate the tensions brought about by (dependent) capitalist development and the growing demands of democratic inclusion and participation” (Wehr, Leubolt and Schaffar, 2015[71]).

The third preconception is that developing countries are obliged to channel scarce resources to those most in need. This targeted approach creates a stratified system whereby coverage for formal-sector workers is universal while those outside the formal sector have low coverage and inadequate benefit levels. In reality, universalism was the guiding principle of welfare policies in developing and advanced economies alike in the 1960s and 1970s, but “since the 1980s, the balance has radically tilted in favour of targeting” in both sets of countries (Mkandawire, 2005[69]). In the case of developing countries, the debt crises of the 1980s and 1990s, and the structural adjustment policies imposed subsequently, cemented this ideological shift. It should be noted, however, that many developing countries have retained universal subsidies for staple goods, in particular food and fuel; attempts to remove these subsidies can lead to unrest (Box 4.4).

Proponents of targeting point to the efficiency – and fairness – of directing benefits to individuals who need them most. This argument appears all the more compelling in countries that generate low fiscal revenues or where inequality is high. However, such arguments disregard the challenges inherent to targeting: people move in and out of poverty (especially in urban areas), the poorest people are often those that governments find it hardest to reach, income-based measures of poverty are unreliable, and multi-dimensional indicators are complicated to administer without necessarily generating better results (Brown, Ravallion and van de Walle, 2016[74]).

Targeting also risks undoing the potential gains to social inclusion and social cohesion. Identifying a group as sufficiently poor to warrant government handouts might result in their being resented or stigmatised. Gassmann, Martorano and Waidler show that receipt of social targeted assistance benefits in Kyrgyzstan is associated with lower levels of subjective well-being among young people, who have grown up in a market economy, but not among older citizens, who recall universal social protection provision under Soviet rule (2021[75]). Targeting can also generate divisions between recipients and non-recipients that result in tensions between groups and diminish social capital (Adato, 2000[76]). Community-based approaches can address concerns related to the accuracy of targeting (McCord, 2013[77]); however, as Endris et al. show in the case of Ethiopia, securing the legitimacy of a targeted programme requires embedding it in broader sets of community arrangements (2020[78]). Meanwhile, effective grievance and accountability mechanisms are essential for improving performance and safeguarding the relationship between the state and society (Alik-Lagrange et al., 2021[60]).

Applying conditionalities (such as school attendance or visiting medical facilities) to receipt of social assistance benefits is another mechanism for enhancing the impact of social assistance that has a mixed record, including in terms of strengthening social cohesion and relations between society and the state. Alik-Lagrange et al argue that much depends on programme design, emphasising the importance of aligning conditionalities to people’s rights and expectations, ensuring these conditions are feasible (the services must be accessible in the first place, for example) and that recipients are not punished for non-compliance (2021[60]).

The importance of the latter point is borne out by Heinrich and Knowles, who show that the behaviour of recipients of the Kenya Cash Transfer Programme for Orphans and Vulnerable Children was the same whether benefit receipt was conditional or beneficiaries were simply informed of the desired outcomes but compliance was not monitored (2020[79]). Indeed, the authors showed the punitive conditionalities produced undesirable and regressive outcomes. It is also often the case that the task of adhering to conditionalities falls upon women, thereby reinforcing gender inequalities (Jones and Holmes, 2011[80]).

The cost of universal social protection means it is a long-term objective, especially for low-income countries, which often have large gaps in social protection provision. The COVID-19 pandemic has increased this cost through its impact on incomes and employment. Durán Valverde et al. calculate that developing countries would need to spend an additional 3.8% of GDP per year on average to close the financing gap for the establishment of social protection floors (including health protection) (2020[81]). For upper-middle-income countries, this cost falls to 3.1% of their GDP; for low-income countries, it rises to 15.9% of their GDP – the sum total of their tax revenues as calculated by Akitoby et al (2019[82]).

For developing countries, increasing financing for social protection is inseparable from the broader objective of domestic resource mobilisation. Scaling up social insurance has an obvious role to play in this regard, in spite of the complexities. For low-income countries, however, external support is indispensable, even though this confronts the challenge of social legitimacy: as Devereux and White find, “programmes that emerge out of domestic political agendas and respond to local conceptualisations and prioritisations of need are more likely to “succeed” in terms of their coverage, fiscal sustainability, political institutionalisation and impacts” (2007[83]).

For most developing countries, establishing universal protection systems will take time. A social protection strategy that takes account of the needs of the population today and into the future is essential; so too is a corresponding financing strategy that demonstrates how to sustainably scale up social protection while also promoting shock responsiveness (OECD, 2018[84]). To ensure that the resultant social protection system not only reduces vulnerability but also strengthens social cohesion and reinforces the social contract, both exercises should be based on social dialogues with an array of actors in government, business and civil society (ILO, 2021[85]).

By including the voices of vulnerable members of society, such processes generate a broad-based consensus around the design of social protection systems and individual programmes that strengthens their legitimacy. They also reinforce social protection’s capacity to empower individuals and communities as a means of reducing inequality ex ante. As Lothian and Unger argue, “[the] most important form of redistribution is not retrospective and compensatory redistribution through tax-and-transfer; it is the reshaping of economic and educational arrangements to broaden opportunity and enhance capabilities” (2012[86]).

An understanding of political economy factors is essential for overcoming the three traps identified in the previous section. This section uses the stylised model to understand better the close relationship between economic and political power, which in turn is fundamental to understanding the persistence of inequality in democratic systems. Figure 4.5 represents a society where a relatively small proportion of the population control a disproportionate amount of both forms of power. The dividing line has moved far to the right, with the right-hand triangle constituted by households from what we might consider a secure middle class and upper class. As mentioned earlier, the left-hand side of the triangle, where the precariat is located, is characterised by low levels of civil engagement and the absence of public institutions that might serve as interlocutors with the state and mediators of discontent. There is thus a marked absence of bridging or linking social capital, unlike on the right-hand side.

As discussed in Chapter 3, a concentration of economic resources is easy to understand; a political concentration (outside an authoritarian or theocratic regime) is less intuitive, for the simple reason that, in political terms, everyone along the bottom of the triangle has an equal right to vote and to run for office. Remembering that the position of the red line is the consequence of a series of political choices, it does not make sense that a majority of the population finds itself on the wrong side of it.

Part of the answer lies in a narrowing of political space. Where 20th century politics was characterised by competition between the ideological left and right, the end of the Cold War led to the emergence of so-called Third Way politics, which focused less on ideological rivalries and more on the technical aspects of government. The objective of public administration became to optimise the status quo according to utilitarian principles rather than to promote change, on the grounds that there was no viable alternative to a highly liberalised economic model (Séville, 2017[95]). Declining voter turnouts and distrust in political systems can be understood as a demonstration of the powerlessness voters feel to effect change and the exclusion of their interests from the political discourse.

Social capital is a critical means of engaging citizens within the political system and ensuring their voices are heard. As Almond and Verba put it, “[voluntary] associations are the prime means by which the function of mediating between the individual and the state is performed. Through them the individual is able to relate himself effectively and meaningfully to the political system” (1963[96]). The paucity of civil society in Figure 4.5 can be traced to various economic phenomena, such as the constraints in terms of time and money among the large proportions of the global population who are struggling to get by, as well as the atomisation of workers in a post-industrial society. However, it also reflects a failure by governments to foster and reach out to civil society as a whole.

Where civil society is weak, citizens are deprived of interlocutors between themselves and the state that might hear and address their grievances. As a consequence, their best option is to communicate with the state. This can be done directly (for example, in the form of a protest movement) or via a political party that positions itself as (sole) mediator between this disenfranchised majority and the state. Where such a party takes power, a form of highly centralised or direct rule is likely to ensue: the leadership is apt to bypass the democratic institutions (which are likely to possess much more credibility among those to the right of the line than those to the left) and frame policies as being in the interests of “the people”, meaning this majority rather than society as a whole. This is typical of the populist politics discussed in Chapter 3.

Populism can construct adversaries to the people on either side of the red line. When citizens look to the state for a group identity, nationalist and/or majoritarian impulses focused on two common enemies are likely to emerge. In the first, the disenfranchised group (via its political representatives) might focus on the “elite” to the right of the line, whose economic and political power they seek to reduce and redistribute more equitably. Alternatively, the common enemies might be the “outsiders” (either within or outside the borders) who compete for resources, such as employment or public services.

Adverse alliances can form between elites and the precariat. Citizens either side of the red line can find common cause even without sharing social capital. Indeed, a lack of social capital among citizens on the left-hand side (including the precariat described in Chapter 1) weakens this group’s political identity. This in turn deprives a country’s political system of a recognisable structure and discourse. Political movements (led by new or established parties) can manufacture an identity for the precariat that is likely to emphasise ethno-nationalist symbols rather than specific policy positions as a common denominator for a highly diverse constituency. This provides the political movement with mass support for its broader political agenda, which can justify a broad range of policies with recourse to narratives rather than a technical logic. This alliance might be effective where governments oppose international regulation for the benefit of large domestic businesses but justify their position with reference to the national interest.

Populist movements eliminate (or appear to eliminate) the red line separating political insiders and outsiders but are likely to find it difficult to move the economic red line. It is worth remembering that it requires a concerted push along the length of the economic red line involving various sets of public and private institutions working in partnership and engaging the citizenry in collaborative endeavours to make an economy and a society function more inclusively. This is difficult to achieve in polarised societies where intermediary institutions are sparse and democratic institutions weak or discredited. Where governments fail to improve the conditions of the precariat, frustration is likely to ensue; this frustration might lead to the removal of the non-performing government at the next election, but it might also be directed at the aforementioned common enemies, leading to further division and rendering collective action even harder to achieve. Another vicious circle arises.

Greater civic engagement offers a path to greater inclusion. The rise of populist movements demonstrates the close links between social, economic and political exclusion, as well as the dangers thereof when a large portion of the population finds itself excluded from the most profitable (in the broadest sense of the term) operations of the society. Absence of social capital – and the associated lack of agency and empowerment – lies at the heart of each of these forms of exclusion; efforts to strengthen social capital should be pursued in the three spheres.

Civic engagement can foster a group identity and enhance individual status. A functional approach, such as the one outlined in this chapter, places people in relation to each other in spatial terms (defined by material and institutional parameters), but it does not convey an identity per se. This is a shortcoming in a context where an important attraction of populist movements is the associated sense of belonging and relatedness among individuals who have lost their identity because, as discussed earlier in this report, their identity (and social standing) was closely linked to a particular profession. Their economic value might have depreciated and with it their status and self-worth, but the skills they possess might be no less valuable socially. Finding outlets for those skills through collective activities has the potential to achieve a better balance between what the economy (in all its globalised variability) values and what society values: a recipe for reducing discontent and strengthening social cohesion.

Throughout this chapter, the model assumes that state and society remain locked together, even if the flows of resources, reciprocity and influence between them vary. The possibility needs to be acknowledged that a population within a society might not feel bound to a specific state at all and therefore wishes to secede. If successful, a new state is constituted by this group and is presumably more representative of the group’s particular needs. Alternatively, a country might be trying hard to integrate a geographical area or population with a different identity into prevailing national institutions. As Escobar describes with reference to populations living on the Pacific coast of Colombia, the legitimacy of such a project requires consideration of place, capital, nature, development, identity and networks that permit the group being integrated to retain its distinctiveness (2008[97]).

It is also important to note that the size of a polity (understood as the state and society) might vary over time, depending on the purpose it is intended to serve. Turchin, for example, argues that throughout history societies have expanded as an optimal response to conflict (2016[98]). As the threat of war diminishes, this expansion might be reversed. With the frequency of international conflict greatly diminished in most parts of the world in the past century (Gleditsch and Pickering, 2014[99]), the structure of nation states is increasingly influenced by the demands of the globalised economy, as Chapter 5 explains. Social cohesion at a national level is likely to depend in large part on policies to close the subnational divides discussed in Chapter 1 (Box 4.5).

Inclusiveness can be hardwired into the rules by which a country is governed through a constitution that sets out universal rights. More than that, a constitution is fundamental to the social contract in a given society, serving as an institution that articulates and codifies the values that a society considers essential at a moment in time. However, there is no guarantee these rights can be realised: socio-economic rights such as access to basic services and employment depend on the resources at a country’s disposal (Litinski, 2019[107]). Consequently, constitutions such as South Africa’s commit to the progressive realisation of such rights (Chenwi, 2013[108]). Moreover, countries are apt to change the rules more often than one might expect: the mean duration of a written constitution since 1789 is 17 years, the median 8 years and the mode just 1 (Ginsburg, Elkins and Melton, 2007[109]).

This section contends that a national strategy is an essential, forward-looking complement to a constitution. If compiled with the extensive collaboration of citizens, a national strategy provides a bottom-up legitimation for the state that mirrors and reinforces the top-down validation provided by a constitution. Moreover, a national strategy has the potential to chart a path towards the realisation of socio-economic rights for the population as a whole and to demonstrate in concrete terms how each citizen and each region is reflected in – and will contribute to – a country’s vision for the future.

Constitutional reform has been widespread over the past decade. As the example of Chile in Chapter 2 demonstrates, it is sometimes the case that only a commitment to redrawing the fundamental rules and institutions that govern society can satisfy demands for systemic change and social equality (Abebe et al., 2020[110]). Constitutional reform in many parts of the world has strengthened socio-economic rights and opened the way for greater female participation. Many reform processes have involved much higher levels of public participation. Yet the story has not been universally positive: authoritarian regimes have used constitutional change to legitimise their regime or curtail democratic impulses; even in democratic settings, powerful groups have wielded disproportionate influence on constitution building or blocked legislative approval. Constitutional reform has also proven ineffective as a tool for conflict resolution due to the challenges of securing buy-in from rival factions (Abebe et al., 2020[110]).

It is much too early to know whether recent constitutional reforms will help provide lasting solutions to the phenomena behind discontent, but it is important to recognise constitutional reform as only one step in the journey towards fairer and more inclusive societies. Giving effect to the constitution is a day-to-day responsibility of the state and society as a whole: socio-economic rights such as access to basic services or opportunities for employment can only be realised – can only be meaningful – if governments are able to provide services and if work is available. The rules of the game require a strategy for implementation that follows the same principles emerging in constitution building – a guaranteed standard of living for all citizens and inclusiveness as a principle both of formulation and realisation – but which also reflects the material constraints that countries confront.

While the number of countries amending their constitutions has grown in recent years, so too has the number that are setting out national development strategies. The number of countries producing national strategies increased from 62 in 2006 to 134 in 2018. More than 80% of the world’s population lives in a country with a national development plan, a number which might rise further as governments contemplate their recovery from the COVID-19 pandemic. These strategies have the potential to be far more than a roadmap to a future desired by the administration of the day. If implemented correctly, they are inclusive in both ends and means: while the final objective should be a collective vision of the future in which every citizen (or region) can see their place, the process of negotiating this vision should be an opportunity for a broad range of voices from across society to be heard.

A national development strategy should not be confused with centralised planning or production quotas. Rather, a key aspect of a national development strategy is its ability to embed an economic project within a broader set of national priorities. To ensure its legitimacy, the process of identifying these priorities should not be carried out in a top-down manner or as a technical process but as a collective exercise in participatory democracy. Getting the modalities of participation correct is a delicate task, but it is paramount that whatever process emerges is able to circumvent prevailing power structures to avoid the risk that these prescribe a country’s future trajectory.

A successful strategy is guided by a robust understanding of a country’s capabilities and how these capabilities will develop over time. The ability to mobilise and co-ordinate various stakeholders and actors at different stages of the process is also critical, as is an appreciation of how a country is positioned internationally. A good strategy combines a multi-dimensional approach to development with the ability to prioritise among dimensions and ensure coherence among activities. Effective implementation (closely monitored) is also key, likewise the principle that national strategies are not one-off exercises. Each strategy will have a successor: the country’s capabilities are enhanced with each iteration, allowing each strategy to be more ambitious than the last.

According to Chimhowu, Hulme and Munro, today’s strategies are underpinned by one of two different logics, which they refer to as “linear” and “collaborative” (2019[111]). Linear rationality follows classical planning techniques, a technocratic exercise based on a top-down, problem-solving approach to development reliant on scientific expertise, abundant data and a toolkit of appropriate policies; decisions are guided by cost-benefit analysis and efficiency benchmarks. Under a collaborative rationality, meanwhile, planning is

a process of negotiating and communicating across communities and citizenries about shared values, cause-effect relationships and probable outcomes. The national plan is not so much a set of decisions as an important and ongoing element of social deliberation that involves constantly (re)negotiating goals and policies/actions so that choices are made that are technically desirable and politically feasible. (Chimhowu, Hulme and Munro, 2019[111])

While the advantages of collaborative rationality from a social capital perspective are clear, the time it takes to achieve consensus might delay the planning process, and the aforementioned point about power asymmetries jeopardising the legitimacy of strategic planning remains.

When examining the strategies currently in effect, Chimhowu, Hulme and Munro recognise that linear and collaborative approaches differ in the extent to which they are evidence based (2019[111]). The authors establish a four-type classification: 26% of plans have a linear rationality with a strong evidence base, 12% a linear rationality with a weak evidence base, 42% a collaborative rationality with a strong evidence base and 20% a collaborative rationality with a weak evidence base. These numbers suggest that one-third of national plans in effect today lack a strong intellectual foundation; among the rest, there is a tendency towards collaborative approaches that are bottom up and socially embedded. This trend has been accompanied by a diminished role for ministries of finance, which might account for a lack of a clear programme in many countries as to how a strategy will be financed.

The new generation of strategies, especially those with a collaborative rationale, imply a new approach to government predicated on regular engagement between society and the state and learning-by-doing. The OECD draws attention to the concept of problem-driven iterative adaptation, which consists of “proposing strategies that begin with generating locally nominated and prioritised problems, and working iteratively to identify customised ‘best fit’ responses” (2018[112]). This is consistent with the experimental approach mentioned above.

Chimhowu, Hulme and Munro also find that national development strategies increasingly mention global challenges, especially climate change: “[to] a degree, it is as if the national development plan is an opportunity for a country to show it is a ‘good global citizen’ responding to a common agenda” (2019[111]). It also makes sense: given that many global challenges impinge on a country’s development (as Chapter 5 explains), reflecting these in a national strategy is an important means of ensuring its resilience and effectiveness. This endeavour is not without its complications, however, and not just because of the inherent uncertainty. As Box 4.6 discusses, today’s environmental crises demand a complete change in the way countries conceive of the relationship between the economy, society and the environment, while the global importance of a country’s environmental policies complicates the governance of natural resource management.

As the COVID-19 pandemic has demonstrated, shocks from outside a country’s borders have the power not only to derail a national development strategy but also to undo past progress. Writing in the wake of the global financial crisis, Lothian and Unger argue that this vulnerability calls for a “paced and limited integration into the world economy, subordinated to the requirements of a national development strategy” (2012[86]). Echoing a number of points made in this chapter, they conclude that

the best is a movement that enhances integration but seeks to shape it in the service of a project designed to create new comparative advantages. The most effective way to create them is not dogmatically to choose sectors that are supposedly bearers of the future (as if the future did not have to make its own choices). It is to empower experimentalism: by establishing arrangements that broaden economic and educational opportunity, by giving small and medium-size business access to forms of credit, technology, marketing, and knowledge normally reserved to big businesses, by propagating successful local practice, and, above all, by creating the means and the conditions for pluralism and experimentation in the institutional forms of the market economy – that is to say, in the ways of organizing production and exchange.

This chapter outlines a range of mechanisms whereby states and societies work together to generate inclusive growth, establish stronger, more responsive institutions and reduce vulnerabilities. These can feed off each other, generating virtuous circles that not only improve development outcomes but also enhance social cohesion by fostering inclusion, co-operation and trust. However, the current context presents some major impediments to getting these approaches off the ground: the COVID-19 pandemic has taken a heavy toll on the economy and public finances, worsened poverty and inequality and, in many cases, further polarised societies. This section identifies three interconnected challenges that arise from this context: a lack of financing, an emphasis on resilience (narrowly defined) over innovation, and the impact of inequality on participatory processes.

The COVID-19 pandemic has dealt a major blow to public finances, especially in developing countries. Tax revenues in countries across Latin America and the Caribbean, for example, fell 11.2% in 2020 at the same time as governments in the region scaled up public spending to protect incomes, jobs and livelihoods (OECD et al., 2021[122]). Fiscal deficits widened, and the region’s debt levels jumped by ten percentage points from the previous year to an average of 56% of GDP (NU CEPAL, 2021[123]). While the output of OECD economies is expected to recover to pre-crisis levels in 2021, it could take much longer in many developing countries; tax revenues will remain subdued as a result.

This drop in revenues, compounded by rising debt costs, will narrow the fiscal space available to developing countries. There is little support nationally or internationally for austerity policies intended to accelerate fiscal consolidation by cutting spending: as mentioned in Chapter 1, this approach contributed to the slow recovery from the global financial crisis, and countries today are encouraged to maintain an expansionary fiscal policy until a recovery is well established (OECD, 2020[124]). Nonetheless, it will be difficult for governments to finance the higher public investment in the economy, better public services and broader social protection coverage that can serve as a catalyst for these virtuous circles. Indeed, there is a risk the opposite will happen, reinforcing the development traps: public investment might fall, jobs might remain scarce, public services could deteriorate further, and poverty and inequality might rise. Discontent would likely worsen as a result, amplifying the challenge of achieving a political consensus for the structural reforms the approaches outlined here might require.

A comparison between the average tax structures of developing countries with that of OECD members demonstrates that scope exists to increase tax revenues, even taking into account the structural economic differences. Personal income tax (PIT) and social security contributions generate a much higher proportion of revenues in OECD countries than in Africa and LAC (Figure 4.6). Revenues from these instruments, whose base is greatly constrained by large-scale informality in developing countries, are also much higher as a percentage of GDP in OECD countries. PIT revenues are also constrained by the ability of high net worth individuals to hide money abroad (OECD, 2016[125]).

On the other hand, taxes on goods and services generate a much larger share of revenues in Africa and LAC than they do in OECD countries, on average. So too does corporate income tax. Nonetheless, these categories are often operating below their full potential in developing countries due to a combination of tax evasion (especially by multinational enterprises) and tax incentives. Subsidies on value added tax can help ensure staple goods remain affordable for low-income households, while tax incentives can be an important instrument for industrial development or attracting investment.

According to the Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean and Oxfam International, tax expenditures for these different objectives in Latin America were equivalent to 3.7% of GDP on average between 2016 and 2019, or around 25% of tax revenue, excluding social contributions (2020[126]). It is important to understand who benefits from these different sets of subsidies and to know what countries get in return for the economic incentives. Social protection benefits are increasingly recognised as a more effective way of supporting the consumption of low-income households, while in many places, the economic case for tax subsidies for businesses appears weak (Brys et al., 2016[127]; Izquierdo et al., 2020[128]).

There is scope for developing countries to increase revenues from a range of tax taxes with valuable externalities. Environmental taxes, an important mechanism for deterring activities that are harmful to the environment, generate a lower proportion of revenues in developing countries than in the OECD (OECD, 2021[129]). The same can be said of taxes on immovable property (often referred to simply as ‘property taxes’) , even though these are a key source of financing for local governments looking to improve basic services, especially in contexts of rapid urbanisation. They can also be progressive (Norregaard, 2013[130]). Wealth taxes can play an important role in reducing inequality and enhancing equality of opportunity but the number of countries that implemented taxes on net wealth in the OECD declined from 12 in 1990 to 4 in 2017 (OECD, 2018[131]). There is a strong case for implementing wealth taxes in developing countries but very few do so (Londoño-Vélez and Ávila-Mahecha, 2021[132]). The OECD finds that taxes on inheritance are not operating at their full potential, even in OECD countries (2021[133]).

While the scope to increase revenues in order to finance better public services and promote redistribution exists, the tax reforms required to achieve these increases might very well be politically contentious. As Gómez Sabaini, Jiménez and Martner Fanta explain, contestation over tax policy is inevitable, given the inherent need to balance the imperatives of efficiency (in particular, minimising economic distortions) with equity in taxation, and given the differing views that exist within any society concerning the role and size of the state (2017[134]). Different groups will have different positions on these questions, with the more powerful groups, such as business associations, apt to have views on income taxes, for example, that are not shared by the more vulnerable members of society. Fairfield finds evidence of this phenomenon in Chile’s tax policy during the two decades following the return to democracy in 1990 (2014[135]).

Achieving strong and broad popular consensus for tax reforms is therefore vital. A fiscal pact across a broad range of stakeholders that reflects a shared understanding of what these reforms will achieve and a broad-based agreement as to how the cost will be shared would provide a strong and sustained foundation for such a reform programme. Fiscal pacts require a long time horizon: comprehensive tax reforms typically take a number of years to enact and will therefore require a commitment that spans administrations. Fiscal pacts also confront the fact that the majority of people have a poor understanding of tax policy and can thus be manipulated by the media (which, as discussed in Chapter 3, might have vested interests of their own). As Tetlow et al. put it with reference to the United Kingdom, “[the] only popular tax … is the tax that somebody else pays … [Getting] the politics right is the most important thing” (2020[136]).

There are at least four reasons why the COVID-19 pandemic might facilitate fiscal pacts. First, crises make structural reforms easier, as the experience of OECD countries after the global financial crisis demonstrates (OECD, 2012[137]). Second, the pandemic has underlined the importance of public goods and the vital role of the state in times of crisis. Third, the importance of tax policy has been underlined by its prominence in countries’ responses to the crisis (2021[138]). Fourth, the pandemic demonstrated that tax systems can be an effective means of providing support to businesses and individuals, implying a two-way flow of funds between the state and registered tax payers and entities. In this context, informal workers and enterprises might be encouraged to make themselves visible to tax administrations. Any fiscal pact should promote fair treatment of men and women by the tax system to avoid reinforcing gender inequalities (Harding, Perez-Navarro and Simon, 2020[139]).

International support for these efforts is essential. As Chapter 5 discusses, international co-operation on taxation is essential to ensure multinational enterprises and high net worth individuals pay their fair share of taxes on income and wealth, particularly for their activities in developing countries (Zucman, 2014[140]). Taxing the digital economy is a challenge countries cannot confront individually (OECD, 2020[141]). Meanwhile, developing countries saddled with even larger debt burdens following the COVID-19 pandemic will be severely constrained without support from creditors (public and private) and could face financial crisis in the near future (UNSDG, 2021[142]).

As the world has grown more interconnected, humans have become ever-more reliant on increasingly complex systems across all areas of life. These systems are undergoing profound changes and, as COVID-19 demonstrated, are highly vulnerable (Hynes, Lees and Müller, 2020[143]). This vulnerability is in large part a consequence of human behaviours discussed in this report. As Friedman puts it:

Over the past 20 years, we’ve been steadily removing man-made and natural buffers, redundancies, regulations and norms that provide resilience and protection when big systems – be they ecological, geopolitical or financial – get stressed. We’ve been recklessly removing these buffers out of an obsession with short-term efficiency and growth, or without thinking at all (2020[144]).

The pandemic’s aforementioned impact on public finances is likely to result in an emphasis on maximising the impact of budgetary outlay. Resilience and efficiency are likely to be the watchwords of public policy in the near future; the risks inherent to innovation and the transaction costs (economic and temporal) associated with inclusive processes could push both into the background.

Such distinctions are misleading and muddied by definitional uncertainty. What do we mean by resilience? In one sense, resilience is the ability to withstand a shock such that the entity emerges unscathed. In another, it is an entity’s ability to adapt to a shock, surviving in a different form. A linear approach to planning discussed earlier will prioritise the former to ensure a plan is resilient; a collaborative approach will emphasise the latter to build a more resilient society. Creating space for innovation – and allocating resources to this end – is central to the ability to adapt.

Moreover, conventional measures of efficiency might not reflect the non-economic indicators discussed in this report. Traditional cost-benefit analysis cannot pick up feelings of agency or solidarity any better than it does distrust and alienation. Unless these measures are recalibrated to reflect improvements in trust in institutions or between people, they will neglect an important facet of what these innovations are trying to achieve. At the same time, standard measures of efficiency can demonstrate the effectiveness of a policy innovation and show ways it might be enhanced.

A tension also exists between resilience and efficiency. Resilience entails spare capacity and redundancy in public systems in case a shock occurs – think empty hospital beds and unused ventilators, for example. Meanwhile, a focus on efficiency reduces redundancy through probabilistic models that might function well for a prolonged period but be ill equipped for large and/or covariate macro-level shocks. The time frame over which efficiency is measured can make a large difference to the calculations.

Ultimately, the present fiscal constraints, the nature of the challenges societies confront and the uncertainty of our era require systemic approaches that combine efficiency, resilience and innovation. Indeed, policies and processes should be framed in these terms. At the same time, these concepts do not necessarily emphasise another prerequisite for the post-pandemic era: inclusivity.

The COVID-19 pandemic has caused inequality to widen across a number of key dimensions (Stantcheva, 2021[145]). The mechanisms outlined in this chapter are intended to tackle inequality of various types – social, political and economic – at the source. However, participatory processes carry the risk of compounding rather than alleviating inequality across these dimensions if disadvantaged groups are excluded. The greater the capacity of these processes to redistribute power and resources, the larger their transformative potential but also the larger this risk.

Kern and Hooghe find evidence from a sample of European countries of what they call a democratic paradox, whereby “a proliferation of forms of participation in practice leads to more inequality” (2018[146]). The authors conclude that “[the] more opportunities there are for participation, the easier it will be for citizens with a high level of political resources to use those opportunities to make sure their interests are being taken into account by the political system. Citizens with fewer skills and resources, on the other hand, are much less apt to use all these opportunities”. They also point to the possibility of democracy fatigue, whereby citizens eventually switch off from regular political engagement; as one example, Switzerland makes extensive use of direct democracy but electoral turnouts are low relative to other European countries.

Such arguments do not undermine the case for broader citizen engagement in public life; this chapter has sought to articulate the potential of inclusive processes to achieve a double dividend in alleviating discontent insofar as they provide mechanisms for voice and can strengthen development outcomes. Moreover, it has shown how developing countries have been more influential in the global diffusion of participatory processes than advanced economies in recent years. Nonetheless, these arguments demonstrate the need for participatory processes to be carefully designed so as to empower those most at risk of exclusion. These arguments also underline how difficult it is to implement these processes once inequality has become entrenched: they tend to be more effective as prevention rather than cure.

The higher the level of inequality, the harder it is to proceed with some of these approaches. Ferragina emphasises “the importance of equality of conditions in building a cohesive society”, arguing that, while social capital is an important mechanism for promoting equality in society, a certain degree of equality is a prerequisite for the building of social capital (2010[147]). As Lustig explains, the weak fiscal capacity in the majority of developing countries relative to advanced economies is a major impediment to redistribution and poverty alleviation (2017[148]). Low revenues also weaken the resilience of public finances by diminishing the counter-cyclicality of fiscal systems (Égert, 2014[149]).

However, a larger government does not necessarily entail lower levels of inequality: the extent of fiscal redistribution depends on how revenues are raised and how they are spent. As discussed in Chapter 3, efforts to reduce inequality depend not only on political will but also on prevailing social attitudes towards inequality. A critical question as the world emerges from the COVID-19 pandemic is whether these attitudes have changed (Wiwad et al., 2021[150]).

The approaches outlined in this chapter have the potential to catalyse inclusive economic growth in the wake of the COVID-19 pandemic through enhanced co-operation predicated on a logic of collaborative networks, shared know-how, stronger social cohesion and a more robust social contract. At the same time, they address discontent by connecting individuals to the life of a nation, thereby providing them with voice and agency. To achieve their potential, these approaches require the participation and interaction of individuals and institutions across the length and breadth of society: they are bottom-up but rely on government reaching down to help. Moreover, these partnerships must act in co-ordination with one another, which implies not only adherence to a common plan but also a common way of working.

This is not so much a long-term project as an infinite one: regardless of a country’s level of development, excluding groups from society’s day-to-day functioning is both symptom and cause of dysfunctional governance, a breach of the social contract and a failure to harness a population’s full potential. The collaborative approaches outlined here need careful design, might work slowly at times and do not negate the importance of the traditional tools for optimising the use of public resources. However, such processes are likely to hold the key to making societies not only more stable and cohesive but also better able to address the challenges of today and tomorrow.

To understand whether or not the kind of approaches outlined here are successful, governments will need to focus on the (albeit disparate) measures of social cohesion, as well as levels of inequality, rather than look narrowly at measures of per capita income, to derive a better understanding of not only the health of society but also its future prospects. A broad-based approach to welfare, which explicitly acknowledges differences across society without attempting to impose a ranking on them, is foundational to the OECD’s Better Life index, the United Nations’ Human Development Index and the work on multi-dimensional poverty, which recognise the importance of consumption to well-being but reflect numerous other factors as well, including the environment. Indeed, a reconceptualisation of the relationship between the economy, society and the environment will be critical to achieving global environmental goals.

A limitation of the model discussed in this chapter is that it excludes other countries. It is easy to imagine how international factors might undermine the approaches for escaping development traps outlined here. The rules that govern global trade – and the robustness of global trade at any point in time – will profoundly affect the likelihood of escaping the productivity trap. If multinational enterprises do not pay their fair share of taxes in the country where they operate, it will be far harder to escape the institutional trap.

The degree of interconnectedness evident today and the global risks humanity confronts have the capacity to overwhelm a country’s strategies. They also challenge governance models and alter the relationship between citizens and the state. The next chapter discusses the role of international co-operation and global governance in helping or hindering developing countries to realise their ambitions and in promoting or preventing the co-operation between countries needed to confront the challenges of this age.

References

[110] Abebe, A. et al. (2020), Annual Review of Constitution Building: 2019, International Institute for Democracy and Electoral Assistance, Stockholm, https://doi.org/10.31752/idea.2020.67 (accessed on 7 February 2021).

[5] Acemoglu, D., S. Johnson and J. Robinson (2004), “Institutions as the Fundamental Cause of Long-Run Growth”, NBER Working Paper, No. 10481, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA, https://doi.org/10.3386/w10481.

[76] Adato, M. (2000), The impact of PROGRESA on community social relationships, International Food Policy Research Institute, https://www.ifpri.org/publication/impact-progresa-community-social-relationships.

[82] Akitoby, B. et al. (2019), “Case studies in tax revenue mobilization in low-income countries”, IMF Working Paper, No. 19/104, International Monetary Fund, https://www.imf.org/en/Publications/WP/Issues/2019/05/14/Case-Studies-in-Tax-Revenue-Mobilization-in-Low-Income-Countries-46719 (accessed on 29 May 2021).

[91] Algan, Y. et al. (2019), Les Origines Du Populisme: Enquête sur un schisme politique et social, Seuil et La République des Idées, Paris, http://www.seuil.com/ouvrage/les-origines-du-populisme-yann-algan/9782021428582 (accessed on 2 February 2021).

[60] Alik-Lagrange, A. et al. (2021), “Social protection and state–society relations in environments of low and uneven state capacity”, Annual Review of Political Science, Vol. 24/1, pp. 151-174, https://doi.org/10.1146/annurev-polisci-041719-101929.

[96] Almond, G. and S. Verba (1963), The Civic Culture: Political Attitudes and Democracy in Five Nations, Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ, https://press.princeton.edu/books/hardcover/9780691651682/the-civic-culture (accessed on 10 February 2021).

[121] Ambrose, J. (2021), ‘Black Wednesday’ for big oil as courtrooms and boardrooms turn on industry, The Guardian, https://www.theguardian.com/environment/2021/may/29/black-wednesday-for-big-oil-as-courtrooms-and-boardrooms-turn-on-industry (accessed on 31 May 2021).

[8] Amin, A. and N. Thrift (eds.) (2004), The Blackwell Cultural Economy Reader, Blackwell Publishing Ltd., Oxford, United Kingdom, https://doi.org/10.1002/9780470774274.

[38] Andrews, M. (2019), Bar talk: informal social interactions, alcohol prohibition, and invention, National Bureau of Economic Research, https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3489466.

[43] Andriani, L. et al. (2021), “Is tax morale culturally driven?”, Journal of Institutional Economics, pp. 1-18, https://doi.org/10.1017/S1744137421000072.

[2] Arrow, K. (1951), Social Choice and Individual Values, John Wiley & Sons, New York.

[62] Babajanian, B. (2012), Social Protection and its Contribution to Social Cohesion and State Building, Deutsche Gesellschaft für Internationale Zusammenarbeit, Bonn, Germany, http://www.socialcohesion.info/fileadmin/user_upload/Social_Protection_and_its__Contribution_to_Social_Cohesion_GIZ.pdf.

[61] Babajanian, B. and J. Hagen-Zanker (2012), “Social protection and social exclusion: an analytical framework to assess the links”, Background Note, Overseas Development Institute, London, https://cdn.odi.org/media/documents/7864.pdf.

[100] Barca, F. (2009), An Agenda for Reformed Cohesion Policy: A place-based approach to meeting European Union challenges and expectations, European Commission, Brussels, https://ec.europa.eu/regional_policy/archive/policy/future/barca_en.htm (accessed on 11 February 2021).

[102] Bartels, K. (2009), “The Disregard for Weber’s Herrschaft: The relevance of Weber’s ideal type of bureaucracy for the modern study of public administration”, Administrative Theory & Praxis, Vol. 31/4, pp. 447-478, https://doi.org/10.2753/atp1084-1806310401.

[35] Becattini, G. (2017), “The Marshallian industrial district as a socio-economic notion”, Revue d’Economie Industrielle, Vol. 157/1, pp. 13-32, https://doi.org/10.4000/rei.6507.

[32] Berger, S. and M. Piore (1980), Dualism and Discontinuity in Industrial Societies, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, United Kingdom, http://www.cambridge.org/fr/academic/subjects/politics-international-relations/comparative-politics/dualism-and-discontinuity-industrial-societies?format=HB&isbn=9780521231343 (accessed on 8 February 2021).

[11] Bisin, A. and T. Verdier (2017), “On the Joint Evolution of Culture and Institutions”, NBER Working Paper, No. 23375, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA, https://doi.org/10.3386/w23375.

[65] Bosch, M., Á. Melguizo and C. Pagés (2013), Better Pensions, Better Jobs: Towards Universal Coverage in Latin America and the Caribbean, Inter-American Development Bank, https://publications.iadb.org/en/better-pensions-better-jobs-towards-universal-coverage-latin-america-and-caribbean-0 (accessed on 26 June 2019).

[9] Bourdieu, P. (1984), Distinction: A Social Critique of the Judgement of Taste, Routledge, London, http://www.routledge.com/Distinction-A-Social-Critique-of-the-Judgement-of-Taste/Bourdieu/p/book/9780415567886#:~:text=Pierre%20Bourdieu%27s%20Distinction%20brilliantly%20illuminates,dissection%20of%20the%20bourgeois%20mind (accessed on 9 February 2021).

[20] Bourdieu, P. (1980), “Le capital social”, in Actes de la Recherche en Sciences Sociales, Persée, Lyon, France, http://www.persee.fr/doc/arss_0335-5322_1980_num_31_1_2069 (accessed on 9 February 2021).

[30] Brighenti, A. (2016), “Antonio Gramsci’s theory of the civil society”, in Handbuch Kultursoziologie, Springer Fachmedien Wiesbaden, Wiesbaden, Germany, https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-658-08000-6_72-1.

[117] Brondizio, E. et al. (eds.) (2019), Global assessment report on biodiversity and ecosystem services of the Intergovernmental Science-Policy Platform on Biodiversity and Ecosystem Services, IPBES secretariat, Bonn, Germany.

[74] Brown, C., M. Ravallion and D. van de Walle (2016), “A poor means test? Econometric targeting in Africa”, Policy Research Working Paper, No. 7915, World Bank Group, Washington, DC, https://doi.org/10.1596/1813-9450-7915.

[36] Brusco, S. (1982), “The Emilian model: Productive decentralisation and social integration”, Cambridge Journal of Economics, Vol. 6/2, pp. 167-84, https://doi.org/10.1093/oxfordjournals.cje.a035506.

[33] Brusco, S. and C. Sabel (1981), “Artisan production and economic growth”, in Wilkinson, F. (ed), The Dynamics of Labour Market Segmentation, Academic Press, London, http://www.elsevier.com/books/the-dynamics-of-labour-market-segmentation/wilkinson/978-0-12-752080-3.

[127] Brys, B. et al. (2016), Tax Design for Inclusive Economic Growth, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://doi.org/10.1787/5jlv74ggk0g7-en.

[56] Cabannes, Y. (2015), “The impact of participatory budgeting on basic services: municipal practices and evidence from the field”, Environment and Urbanization, Vol. 27/1, pp. 257-284, https://doi.org/10.1177/0956247815572297.

[103] Camussi, S. and A. Mancini (2019), “Individual trust: does quality of local institutions matter?”, Journal of Institutional Economics, Vol. 15/3, pp. 487-503, https://doi.org/10.1017/S1744137418000279.

[57] Célérier, L. and L. Cuenca Botey (2015), “Participatory budgeting at a community level in Porto Alegre: a Bourdieusian interpretation”, Accounting, Auditing and Accountability Journal, Vol. 28/5, pp. 739-772, https://doi.org/10.1108/AAAJ-03-2013-1245.

[108] Chenwi, L. (2013), “Unpacking “progressive realisation”, its relation to resources, minimum core and reasonableness, and some methodological considerations for assessing compliance”, De Jure Law Journal, http://www.saflii.org/za/journals/DEJURE/2013/39.html (accessed on 10 February 2021).

[111] Chimhowu, A., D. Hulme and L. Munro (2019), “The ‘New’ national development planning and global development goals: Processes and partnerships”, World Development, Vol. 120, pp. 76-89, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2019.03.013.

[24] CIVICUS (2020), State of civil society report, https://www.civicus.org/index.php/state-of-civil-society-report-2020.

[120] Cogolati, S., L. Hamid and N. Vanstappen (2016), “Global Public Goods and Democracy in International Legal Scholarship”, Cambridge International Law Journal, Vol. 5/1, pp. 4-30, https://doi.org/10.4337/cilj.2016.01.02.

[19] Colletta, N. and M. Cullen (2000), Violent conflict and the transformation of social capital : lessons from Cambodia, Rwanda, Guatemala, and Somalia, World Bank Group, Washington D.C., http://documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/799651468760532921/Violent-conflict-and-the-transformation-of-social-capital-lessons-from-Cambodia-Rwanda-Guatemala-and-Somalia.

[13] Cook, K., R. Hardin and M. Levi (2005), Cooperation Without Trust?, Russell Sage Foundation, New York, http://www.russellsage.org/publications/cooperation-without-trust-0 (accessed on 9 February 2021).

[119] Corfee-Morlot, J. et al. (2009), “Cities, Climate Change and Multilevel Governance”, OECD Environment Working Papers, No. 14, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://doi.org/10.1787/220062444715.

[52] Dante Alighieri (1472), Comedia, Johann Neumeister.

[17] Dasgupta, P. and I. Serageldin (eds.) (1999), Social Capital: A multifaceted perspective, World Bank Group, Washington, DC, http://documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/663341468174869302/Social-capital-a-multifaceted-perspective (accessed on 11 February 2021).

[63] de Milliano, M. et al. (2021), “Crowding-out or crowding-in? Effects of LEAP 1000 unconditional cash transfer program on household and community support among women in rural Ghana”, World Development, Vol. 143, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2021.105466.

[101] Desautels-Stein, J. and T. Christopher (eds.) (2017), Democratic experimentalism, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, United Kingdom, https://core.ac.uk/download/pdf/230174145.pdf (accessed on 11 February 2021).

[83] Devereux, S. and P. White (2007), Pilots, principles or patronage: what makes social protection succeed in Southern Africa?, https://gsdrc.org/document-library/pilots-principles-or-patronage-what-makes-social-protection-succeed-in-southern-africa/ (accessed on 29 May 2021).

[81] Durán Valverde, F. et al. (2020), “Financing gaps in social protection : global estimates and strategies for developing countries in light of the COVID-19 crisis and beyond”, ILO working paper, No. 14, https://www.ilo.org/global/publications/working-papers/WCMS_758705/lang--en/index.htm (accessed on 28 May 2021).

[149] Égert, B. (2014), “Fiscal policy reaction to the cycle in the OECD: pro- or counter-cyclical?”, Mondes en Développement, Vol. 2014/3/167, pp. 35-52, https://doi.org/10.3917/med.167.0035.

[89] El-Katiri, L. and B. Fattouh (2017), “A Brief Political Economy of Energy Subsidies in the Middle East and North Africa”, Revue internationale de politique de développement 7, https://doi.org/10.4000/poldev.2267.

[78] Endris, G. et al. (2020), “How social capital can inform targeting formal social safety net interventions in vulnerable communities in eastern Ethiopia: an ethnographic case study”, Journal of International Humanitarian Action, Vol. 5/1, pp. 1-17, https://doi.org/10.1186/s41018-020-00075-3.

[18] ERIC, IDESO, IDIES, IUDOP (2004), Maras y pandillas en CentroAmérica : pandillas y capital social, volumen II, UCA Editores.

[97] Escobar, A. (2008), Territories of Difference: Place, Movements, Life, Redes, Duke University Press, Durham, NC, http://www.dukeupress.edu/Territories-of-Difference.

[135] Fairfield, T. (2014), “The political economy of progressive tax reform in Chile”, Woodrow Wilson Center Update on the Americas, http://www.wilsoncenter.org/sites/default/files/media/documents/publication/Tax%20Reform%20in%20Chile.pdf.

[147] Ferragina, E. (2010), “Social capital and equality: Tocqueville’s legacy rethinking social capital in relation with income inequalities”, Tocqueville Review, Vol. 31/1, pp. 73-98, https://doi.org/10.1353/toc.0.0030.

[22] Ferragina, E. and A. Arrigoni (2017), “The rise and fall of social capital: Requiem for a theory?”, Political Studies Review, Vol. 15/3, pp. 355-367, https://doi.org/10.1177/1478929915623968.

[49] Freire, P. (1970), Pedagogy of the Oppressed, Herder & Herder, New York, https://envs.ucsc.edu/internships/internship-readings/freire-pedagogy-of-the-oppressed.pdf (accessed on 9 February 2021).

[144] Friedman, T. (2020), “How we broke the world: greed and globalisation set us up for disaster”, New York Times, https://www.nytimes.com/2020/05/30/opinion/sunday/coronavirus-globalization.html (accessed on 24 May 2021).

[15] Fukuyama, F. (1999), Social Capital and Civil Society, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC, http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/seminar/1999/reforms/fukuyama.htm (accessed on 9 February 2021).

[75] Gassmann, F., B. Martorano and J. Waidler (2021), “How social assistance affects subjective well‐being: Lessons from Kyrgyzstan”, UNU-MERIT Working Paper 2021-013, http://www.merit.unu.edu/publications/working-papers/?year_id=2021.

[59] Gentilini, U. et al. (2021), Social Protection and jobs responses to COVID-19 : a real-time review of country measures (14 May 2021 update), World Bank, Washington, DC., https://openknowledge.worldbank.org/handle/10986/33635.

[109] Ginsburg, T., Z. Elkins and J. Melton (2007), The Lifespan of Written Constitutions, UC Berkeley: Berkeley Program in Law and Economics, Berkeley, CA, https://escholarship.org/uc/item/6jw9d0mf (accessed on 11 February 2021).

[99] Gleditsch, K. and S. Pickering (2014), “Wars are becoming less frequent: a response to Harrison and Wolf”, Economic History Review, Vol. 67/1, pp. 214-230, https://doi.org/10.1111/1468-0289.12002.

[134] Gómez Sabaini, J., J. Jiménez and R. Martner Fanta (2017), Consensos y Conflictos en la Política Tributaria de América Latina, United Nations Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean, Santiago, http://www.cepal.org/es/publicaciones/41048-consensos-conflictos-la-politica-tributaria-america-latina.

[54] Group, W. (2008), Brazil: Toward a More Inclusive and Effective Participatory Budget in Porto Alegre, Volume 1. Main Report, World Bank Group, Washington, DC, https://openknowledge.worldbank.org/handle/10986/8042 (accessed on 9 February 2021).

[90] Gupta, S. et al. (2002), “Issues in domestic petroleum pricing in oil-producing countries”, IMF Working Paper, No. 02/140, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC, http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/wp/2002/wp02140.pdf (accessed on 12 March 2021).

[7] Habermas, J. (1981), The Theory of Communicative Action, Beacon Press, Boston, https://doi.org/10.2307/1955926 (accessed on 9 February 2021).

[139] Harding, M., G. Perez-Navarro and H. Simon (2020), In tax, gender blind is not gender neutral: why tax policy responses to COVID-19 must consider women, ECOSCOPE, https://oecdecoscope.blog/2020/06/01/in-tax-gender-blind-is-not-gender-neutral-why-tax-policy-responses-to-covid-19-must-consider-women/ (accessed on 31 May 2021).

[79] Heinrich, C. and M. Knowles (2020), “A fine predicament: conditioning, compliance and consequences in a labeled cash transfer program”, World Development, Vol. 129, p. 104876, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2020.104876.

[12] Henrich, J. (2020), The WEIRDest People in the World, Farrar, Straus and Giroux, New York, https://us.macmillan.com/books/9780374173227 (accessed on 5 February 2021).

[58] Herzberg, C., Y. Sintomer and G. Allegretti (2013), Learning from the South: Participatory Budgeting Worldwide – an Invitation to Global Cooperation, Global Civic Engagement, Bonn, Germany, http://www.researchgate.net/publication/301680298_Learning_from_the_South_Participatory_Budgeting_Worldwide_-_an_Invitation_to_Global_Cooperation (accessed on 10 February 2021).

[47] Hirschman, A. (1972), Exit, Voice, and Loyalty: Responses to Decline in Firms, Organizations, and States, Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA, http://www.hup.harvard.edu/catalog.php?isbn=9780674276604 (accessed on 9 February 2021).

[115] Howarth, C. et al. (2020), “Building a social mandate for climate action: lessons from COVID-19”, Environmental and Resource Economics, Vol. 76/4, pp. 1107-1115, https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-020-00446-9.

[143] Hynes, W., M. Lees and J. Müller (eds.) (2020), Systemic thinking for policy making: the potential of systems analysis for addressing global policy challenges in the 21st century, New Approaches to Economic Challenges, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://doi.org/10.1787/879c4f7a-en (accessed on 24 May 2021).

[85] ILO (2021), World employment and social outlook – trends 2021, International Labour Office, Geneva, https://www.ilo.org/global/research/global-reports/weso/trends2021/lang--en/index.htm.

[87] IMF (2008), “Fuel and food price subsidies: Issues and reform options”, Policy Paper, http://www.imf.org/en/Publications/Policy-Papers/Issues/2016/12/31/Fuel-and-Food-Price-Subsidies-Issues-and-Reform-Options-PP4293.

[126] International, E. (2020), “Tax incentives for businesses in Latin America and the Caribbean. Summary.”, Project Documents (LC/TS.2020/19), Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean/Oxfam International, Santiago, http://www.cepal.org/sites/default/files/publication/files/45204/S1901195_en.pdf.

[42] Isbell, T. and L. Olan’g (2021), “Troubling tax trends: Fewer Africans support taxation, more say people avoid paying”, Afrobarometer Dispatch, No. 428, https://afrobarometer.org/sites/default/files/publications/Dispatches/ad428-tax_trends_in_africa-weaker_legitimacy_more_avoidance-afrobarometer_dispatch-20feb21.pdf (accessed on 25 March 2021).

[128] Izquierdo, A. et al. (2020), Salir del Túnel Pandémico con Crecimiento y Equidad: Una Estrategia para un Nuevo Compacto Social en América Latina y el Carib, Banco Interamericano de Desarrolloe, New York, https://publications.iadb.org/publications/spanish/document/Salir-del-tunel-pandemico-con-crecimiento-y-equidad-Una-estrategia-para-un-nuevo-compacto-social-en-America-Latina-y-el-Caribe.pdf.

[80] Jones, N. and R. Holmes (2011), “Why is social protection gender-blind? The politics of gender and social protection”, IDS Bulletin, Vol. 42/6, pp. 45-52, https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1759-5436.2011.00272.x.

[146] Kern, A. and M. Hooghe (2018), “The effect of direct democracy on the social stratification of political participation: Inequality in democratic fatigue?”, Comparative European Politics, Vol. 16/4, pp. 724-744, https://doi.org/10.1057/s41295-017-0093-y.

[88] Lindebjerg, E., W. Peng and S. Yeboah (2015), “Do policies for phasing out fossil fuel subsidies deliver what they promise? Social gains and repercussions in Iran, Indonesia and Ghana”, UNRISD Working Paper, No. 2015-1, United Nations Research Institute for Social Development, Geneva, http://www.unrisd.org/80256B3C005BCCF9/search/170D2DA8A96A5352C1257DC40050C975?OpenDocument&cntxt=653D7&cookielang=fr#top (accessed on 2 March 2021).

[37] Lin, J. and J. Nugent (1995), “Institutions and economic development”, in Handbook of Development Economics, Elsevier B.V., Amsterdam, http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S1573447105800105.

[107] Litinski, R. (2019), “Economic rights: Are they justiciable, and should they be?”, Human Rights Magazine, Vol. 44/3, http://www.americanbar.org/groups/crsj/publications/human_rights_magazine_home/economic-justice/economic-rights--are-they-justiciable--and-should-they-be-/ (accessed on 11 February 2021).

[132] Londoño-Vélez, J. and J. Ávila-Mahecha (2021), “Enforcing wealth taxes in the developing world: quasi-experimental evidence from Colombia”, American Economic Review: Insights, Vol. 3/2.

[86] Lothian, T. and R. Unger (2012), “Crisis, slump, superstition and recovery: Thinking and acting beyond vulgar Keynesianism”, Columbia Law and Economics Working Paper, No. 394, Columbia University Center for Law and Economic Studies, New York, https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1780454.

[148] Lustig, N. (2017), “Fiscal policy, income redistribution and poverty reduction in low and middle income countries”, CEQ Working Paper, No. 54, Commitment to Equity Institute, Tulane University, New Orleans, LA, https://commitmentoequity.org/wp-content/uploads/2017/08/CEQ_WP54_Lustig_June2017.pdf (accessed on 10 February 2021).

[55] Marquetti, A., C. Schonerwald da Silva and A. Campbell (2012), “Participatory economic democracy in action”, Review of Radical Political Economics, Vol. 44/1, pp. 62-81, https://doi.org/10.1177/0486613411418055.

[34] Marshall, A. (1879), The Pure Theory of (Domestic) Values, McMaster University Archive for the History of Economic Thought, https://socialsciences.mcmaster.ca/econ/ugcm/3ll3/marshall/domesticvalues.pdf (accessed on 8 February 2021).

[92] Maslow, A. (1943), “A theory of human motivation”, Psychological Review, Vol. 50/4, pp. 370-396, https://doi.org/10.1037/h0054346.

[104] Mazzucato, M. et al. (2021), COVID-19 and the need for dynamic state capabilities : an international comparison, UNDP, New York, https://futureofdevelopment.undp.org/content/fod/en/home/our-products/covid-19-and-the-need-for-dynamic-state-capabilities.html.

[77] McCord, A. (2013), Community-based targeting in the social protection sector, Overseas Development Institute.

[72] Mesa-Lago, C. (1978), Social Security in Latin America: Pressure Groups, Stratification, and Inequality, University of Pittsburgh Press, Pittsburgh, PA, https://digital.library.pitt.edu/islandora/object/pitt:31735057895116.

[69] Mkandawire, T. (2005), “Targeting and universalism in poverty reduction”, Social Policy and Development Programme Paper, No. 23, United Nations Research Institute for Social Development, Geneva, http://www.unrisd.org/unrisd/website/document.nsf/(httpPublications)/955FB8A594EEA0B0C12570FF00493EAA?OpenDocument (accessed on 10 February 2021).

[130] Norregaard, J. (2013), “Taxing immovable property : revenue potential and implementation challenges”, IMF Working Paper, No. 13/129, International Monetary Fund, https://www.imf.org/en/Publications/WP/Issues/2016/12/31/Taxing-Immovable-Property-Revenue-Potential-and-Implementation-Challenges-40594 (accessed on 27 May 2021).

[4] North, D. (1991), “Institutions”, Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 5/1, pp. 97-112, https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.5.1.97.

[123] NU CEPAL (2021), Panorama Fiscal de América Latina y el Caribe 2021: Los desafíos de la política fiscal en la recuperación transformadora pos-COVID-19, United Nations Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean, Santiago, http://www.cepal.org/es/publicaciones/46808-panorama-fiscal-america-latina-caribe-2021-desafios-la-politica-fiscal-la (accessed on 22 April 2021).

[39] Nübler, I. (2014), “A theory of capabilities for productive transformation: Learning to catch up”, in Salazar-Xirinachs, J., I. Nübler and R. Kozul-Wright (eds.), Transforming Economies: Making industrial policy work for growth, jobs and development, International Labour Organization, Geneva, http://www.ilo.org/wcmsp5/groups/public/---dgreports/---inst/documents/publication/wcms_315669.pdf (accessed on 11 February 2021).

[44] OECD (2021), Global Revenue Statistics Database, OECD, https://stats.oecd.org/Index.aspx?DataSetCode=RS_GBL (accessed on 6 March 2021).

[133] OECD (2021), Inheritance Taxation in OECD Countries, OECD Tax Policy Studies, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://doi.org/10.1787/e2879a7d-en.

[138] OECD (2021), Tax Policy Reforms 2021: Special Edition on Tax Policy during the COVID-19 Pandemic, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://dx.doi.org/10.1787/427d2616-en.

[129] OECD (2021), Taxing Energy Use for Sustainable Development: Opportunities for energy tax and subsidy reform in selected developing and emerging economies, OECD Publishing, Paris, http://www.oecd.org/tax/tax-policy/taxing-energy-use-for-sustainable-development.htm (accessed on 21 February 2021).

[141] OECD (2020), Addressing the tax challenges arising from the digitalisation of the economy : highlights, OECD/G20 Inclusive Framework on BEPS, https://www.oecd.org/tax/beps/brochure-addressing-the-tax-challenges-arising-from-the-digitalisation-of-the-economy-october-2020.pdf.

[73] OECD (2020), “Civil service pension reform in developing countries: Experiences and lessons”, Development Policy Papers, No. 33, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://doi.org/10.1787/f872f328-en (accessed on 10 February 2021).

[124] OECD (2020), OECD Economic Outlook, Volume 2020 Issue 2, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://dx.doi.org/10.1787/39a88ab1-en.

[46] OECD (2020), Revenue Statistics in Asian and Pacific Economies, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://doi.org/10.1787/d47d0ae3-en.

[106] OECD (2020), The Territorial Impact of COVID-19: Managing the crisis across levels of government, OECD Publishing, Paris, http://www.oecd.org/coronavirus/policy-responses/the-territorial-impact-of-covid-19-managing-the-crisis-across-levels-of-government-d3e314e1/.

[105] OECD (2019), OECD Regional Outlook 2019: Leveraging Megatrends for Cities and Rural Areas, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://doi.org/10.1787/9789264312838-en.

[66] OECD (2019), Social Protection System Review of Indonesia, OECD Development Pathways, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://dx.doi.org/10.1787/788e9d71-en.

[41] OECD (2019), Tax Morale: What Drives People and Businesses to Pay Tax?, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://dx.doi.org/10.1787/f3d8ea10-en.

[114] OECD (2018), Mainstreaming Biodiversity for Sustainable Development, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264303201-en.

[112] OECD (2018), Perspectives on Global Development 2019: Rethinking Development Strategies, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://dx.doi.org/10.1787/persp_glob_dev-2019-en.

[70] OECD (2018), Social Protection System Review of Kyrgyzstan, OECD Development Pathways, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264302273-en.

[84] OECD (2018), Social Protection System Review: A Toolkit, OECD Development Policy Tools, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264310070-en.

[131] OECD (2018), The role and design of net wealth taxes, OECD Tax Policy Studies, No. 26, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://doi.org/10.1787/9789264290303-en.

[51] OECD (2017), “Citizens with a say”, Trends Shaping Education Spotlights, No. 13, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://doi.org/10.1787/3092726b-en. (accessed on 9 February 2021).

[125] OECD (2016), Automatic Exchange of Financial Account Information: Background information brief, OECD Publishing, http://www.oecd.org/ctp/exchange-of-tax-information/Automatic-Exchange-Financial-Account-Information-Brief.pdf.

[137] OECD (2012), Economic Policy Reforms 2012: Going for Growth, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://dx.doi.org/10.1787/growth-2012-en.

[25] OECD (2011), Perspectives on Global Development 2012: Social Cohesion in a Shifting World, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://doi.org/10.1787/persp_glob_dev-2012-en. (accessed on 8 February 2021).

[31] OECD/CAF/ECLAC/EU (2019), Latin American Economic Outlook 2019: Development in Transition, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://doi.org/10.1787/g2g9ff18-en.

[122] OECD et al. (2021), Revenue Statistics in Latin America and the Caribbean 2021, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://dx.doi.org/10.1787/96ce5287-en-es.

[64] OECD/IDB/CIAT (2016), Taxing Wages in Latin America and the Caribbean 2016, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264262607-en.

[67] OECD/ILO (2019), Tackling Vulnerability in the Informal Economy, Development Centre Studies, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://dx.doi.org/10.1787/939b7bcd-en.

[45] OECD, AUC and ATAF (2020), Revenue Statistics in Africa 2020: 1990-2018, OECD Publishing, Paris, http://www.oecd.org/tax/revenue-statistics-in-africa-2617653x.htm.

[116] Ostrom, E. (1990), Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, United Kingdom, https://doi.org/10.1017/cbo9780511807763.

[68] Packard, T. et al. (2019), Protecting All: Risk Sharing for a Diverse and Diversifying World of Work, World Bank Group, Washington, DC, https://doi.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-1427-3.

[53] Pateman, C. (2012), “Participatory democracy revisited”, Perspectives on Politics, Vol. 10/1, pp. 7-19, https://doi.org/10.1017/S1537592711004877.

[10] Pinxten, W. and J. Lievens (2014), “The importance of economic, social and cultural capital in understanding health inequalities: Using a Bourdieu-based approach in research on physical and mental health perceptions”, Sociology of Health & Illness, Vol. 36/7, pp. 1095-1110, https://doi.org/10.1111/1467-9566.12154.

[93] Poingt, G. (2019), “Européennes: Les candidats veulent concilier ’fin du mois’ et ’fin du monde’”, Le Figaro, http://www.lefigaro.fr/conjoncture/europeennes-les-candidats-veulent-concilier-fin-du-mois-et-fin-du-monde-20190405 (accessed on 10 February 2021).

[29] Polanyi, K. (2001 [1944]), The Great Transformation, Beacon Press, Boston, http://www.beacon.org/The-Great-Transformation-P46.aspx.

[40] Primi, A. (2016), Production Transformation Policy Reviews (PTPRs): A Policy Assessment and Guidance Tool to Improve the Effectiveness of Production Transformation Strategies, OECD Publishing, Paris, http://www.oecd.org/dev/Session2_PTPR.pdf.

[21] Putnam, R. (1995), “Bowling Alone: America’s Declining Social Capital”, Journal of Democracy, Vol. 6/1, pp. 65-78, http://www.journalofdemocracy.org/articles/bowling-alone-americas-declining-social-capital/ (accessed on 4 February 2021).

[94] Rodrik, D. (2020), “The public’s business”, Social Europe 13 October 2020, http://www.socialeurope.eu/the-publics-business (accessed on 10 February 2021).

[48] Rosanvallon, P. (2008), Counter-Democracy: Politics in an Age of Distrust, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, United Kingdom, http://www.cambridge.org/fr/academic/subjects/politics-international-relations/political-theory/counter-democracy-politics-age-distrust?format=HB&isbn=9780521886222 (accessed on 8 February 2021).

[23] Rousseau, J. (1762), Du Contrat Sociale, http://classiques.uqac.ca/classiques/Rousseau_jj/contrat_social/contrat_social.html.

[118] Schuster, R. et al. (2019), “Vertebrate biodiversity on indigenous-managed lands in Australia, Brazil, and Canada equals that in protected areas”, Environmental Science and Policy, Vol. 101, pp. 1-6, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.envsci.2019.07.002.

[3] Sen, A. (1970), Collective Choice and Social Welfare, Holden Day, San Francisco, https://scholar.harvard.edu/sen/publications/collective-choice-and-social-welfare.

[95] Séville, A. (2017), “From ’one right way’ to ’one ruinous way’? Discursive shifts in ’There is no alternative’”, European Political Science Review, Vol. 9/3, pp. 449-470, https://doi.org/10.1017/S1755773916000035.

[26] Shafik, M. (2021), What we owe each other: a new social contract, Princeton University Press, https://www.penguin.co.uk/books/111/1119278/what-we-owe-each-other/9781847926272.html (accessed on 22 May 2021).

[145] Stantcheva, S. (2021), Inequalities in the times of a pandemic, https://scholar.harvard.edu/files/stantcheva/files/stantcheva_covid19_policy.pdf.

[136] Tetlow, G. et al. (2020), Overcoming the Barriers to Tax Reform, Institute for Government, London, http://www.instituteforgovernment.org.uk/publications/overcoming-barriers-tax-reform.

[113] Tilzey, M. (2017), “Reintegrating economy, society, and environment for cooperative futures: Polanyi, Marx, and food sovereignty”, Journal of Rural Studies, Vol. 53, pp. 317-334, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jrurstud.2016.12.004.

[1] Tocqueville, A. (1960 [1835]), De la Démocratie en Amérique, MacMillan & Co Ltd, London, http://classiques.uqac.ca/classiques/De_tocqueville_alexis/democratie_1/democratie_tome1.html.

[98] Turchin, P. (2016), Ultrasociety: How 10,000 years of war made humans the greatest cooperators on Earth, Beresta Books, Chaplin, CT, https://berestabooks.com/ultrasociety/ (accessed on 10 February 2021).

[28] UN (2018), Human Rights and Constitution Making, United Nations, New York, https://dx.doi.org/10.18356/c60619e9-en.

[27] UN (1948), Universal Declaration of Human Rights, https://www.un.org/en/about-us/universal-declaration-of-human-rights (accessed on 22 May 2021).

[50] Unger, R. (2009), The Left Alternative, Verso Books, London, New York, http://www.versobooks.com/books/417-the-left-alternative (accessed on 9 February 2021).

[142] UNSDG (2021), Liquidity and Debt Solutions to Invest in the SDGs: The Time to Act is Now, United Nations Sustainable Development Group, New York, https://unsdg.un.org/resources/liquidity-and-debt-solutions-invest-sdgs-time-act-now.

[6] Weber, M. (1930 [1905]), The Protestant ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism, George Allen & Unwin Ltd., London, https://is.muni.cz/el/1423/podzim2013/SOC571E/um/_Routledge_Classics___Max_Weber-The_Protestant_Ethic_and_the_Spirit_of_Capitalism__Routledge_Classics_-Routledge__2001_.pdf.

[71] Wehr, I., B. Leubolt and W. Schaffar (2015), “Welfare regimes in the global South: A short introduction”, Austrian Journal of Development Studies, Vol. XXVIII, http://www.mattersburgerkreis.at/dl/mOkqJMJknoJqx4KooJK/JEP-1-2012_02_WEHR-ET-AL_Welfare-Regimes-in-the-Global-South-A-Short-Introduction.pdf (accessed on 10 February 2021).

[150] Wiwad, D. et al. (2021), “Recognizing the impact of COVID-19 on the poor alters attitudes towards poverty and inequality”, Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, Vol. 93, p. 104083, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jesp.2020.104083.

[14] Woolcock, M. and D. Narayan (2000), “Social capital: Implications for development theory, research, and policy”, World Bank Research Observer, Vol. 15/2, pp. 225-249, https://doi.org/10.1093/wbro/15.2.225.

[16] World Bank (2001), World Development Report 2000/2001: Attacking Poverty, Oxford University Press Inc. for the World Bank, New York, https://doi.org/10.1596/0-1952-1129-4.

[140] Zucman, G. (2014), “Taxing across borders: tracking personal wealth and corporate profits”, Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 28/4, pp. 121–148.

Metadata, Legal and Rights

This document, as well as any data and map included herein, are without prejudice to the status of or sovereignty over any territory, to the delimitation of international frontiers and boundaries and to the name of any territory, city or area. Extracts from publications may be subject to additional disclaimers, which are set out in the complete version of the publication, available at the link provided.

© OECD 2021

The use of this work, whether digital or print, is governed by the Terms and Conditions to be found at http://www.oecd.org/termsandconditions.